Abstract
The digital content market is undergoing an evolution in networking and digitalization technologies, offering diverse information and services. Due to the characteristics of these emerging technologies, the digital content market is growing rapidly and traditional content providers face service transformation decisions. While a majority of the previous technology adoption studies have focused on the viewpoints of users and customers, cost reduction, or electronic channel related technologies, in this research we analyze the emerging technology adoption decisions of competing firms for providing new content services from a strategic perspective. Utilizing game theoretical models, we examine the effects of market environments (technology cost, channel cannibalization, brand power, brand extension, information asymmetry and market uncertainty) on firms’ adoption decisions. This research contributes a number of unique and interesting implications for the issues of emerging technology adoption for new content service provision.




Similar content being viewed by others
References
Adda J, Ottaviani M (2005) The transition to digital television. Econ Policy 20(41):160–209
Au Y, Kauffman R (2001) Should we wait? Network externalities, compatibility, and electronic billing adoption. J Manage Inform Syst 18(2):47–63
Balasubramanian S (1998) Mail versus mall: a strategic analysis of competition between direct marketers and conventional retailers. Market Sci 17:181–195
Biyalogorsky E, Naik P (2003) Clicks and mortar: the effect of on-line activities on off-line sales. Market Lett 14(1):21–32
Bockstedt JC, Kauffman RJ, Riggins FJ (2006) The move to artist-led on-line music distribution: a theory-based assessment and prospects for structural changes in the digital music market. Int J Electron Commer 10(3):7–38
Bower J, Christensen C (1995) Disruptive technologies: catching the wave. Harvard Bus Rev 73:43–53
Brynjolfsson E, Hu YJ, Rahman MS (2009) Battle of the retail channels: how product selection and geography drive cross-channel competition. Manage Sci 55(11):1755–1765
Chellappa RK, Shivendu S (2003) Pay now or pay later? Managing digital product supply chains. In: International conference on electronic commerce, Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania. ACM, pp 230–234
Cheng Z, Nault BR (2007) Internet channel entry: retail coverage and entry cost advantage. Inform Technol Manage 8(2):111–132
Chiang WK, Chhajed D, Hess JD (2003) Direct marketing, indirect profits: a strategic analysis of dual-channel supply-chain design. Manage Sci 49:1–20
Choi J, Thum M (1998) Market structure and the timing of technology adoption with network externalities. Eur Econ Rev 42(2):225–244
Danaher B, Dhanasobhon S, Smith MD, Telang R (2010) Converting pirates without cannibalizing purchasers: the impact of digital distribution on physical sales and internet piracy. Market Sci 29(6):1138–1151
Davis R (2001) The digital dilemma. Commun ACM 44(2):77–83
Deleersnyder B, Geyskens I, Gielens K, Dekimpe M (2002) How cannibalistic is the Internet channel? a study of the newspaper industry in the United Kingdom and the Netherlands. Int J Res Mark 19(4):337–348
Forman C, Ghose A, Goldfarb A (2009) Competition between local and electronic markets: how the benefit of buying online depends on where you live. Manage Sci 55(1):47–57
Fudenberg D, Tirole J (1985) Preemption and rent equalization in the adoption of new technology. Rev Econ Stud 52(3):383–401
Gallagher S (2002) Key issues to consider in assessing the digital content landscape. ECAR Res Bull 2002(14):1–11
Gans J, Stern S (2003) The product market and the market for ideas: commercialization strategies for technology entrepreneurs. Res Policy 32(2):333–350
Geyskens I, Gielens K, Dekimpe MG (2002) The market valuation of internet channel additions. J Market 66(2):102–119
Global entertainment and media outlook 2010–2014 (2010) PricewaterhouseCoopers. Available at http://www.einnews.com/pr-news/90509-pricewaterhousecoopers-releases-global-entertainment-and-media-outlook-2010-2014. Accessed 12 Jun 2011
Gotz G (2000) Strategic timing of adoption of new technologies under uncertainty: a note. Int J Ind Organ 18(2):369–379
Han JK, Kim N, Kim HB (2001) Entry barriers: a dull-, one-, or two-edged sword for incumbents? Unraveling the paradox from a contingency perspective. J Market 65(1):1–14
Hoppe H (2000) Second-mover advantages in the strategic adoption of new technology under uncertainty. Int J Ind Organ 18(2):315–338
Hoppe H (2002) The timing of new technology adoption: theoretical models and empirical evidence. Manch Sch 70(1):56–76
Huisman K, Kort P (2004) Strategic technology adoption taking into account future technological improvements: a real options approach. Eur J Oper Res 159(3):705–728
IFPI. Digital music report. Available at http://www.ifpi.org/site-content/library/digital-music-report-2006.pdf. Accessed 12 Jun 2011
Jensen R (1982) Adoption and diffusion of an innovation of uncertain profitability. J Econ Theory 27(1):182–193
Jeong BK, Khouja M, Zhao K (2011) The impacts of piracy and supply chain contracts on digital music channel performance. Decis Support Syst (in Press)
Jiang Y, Katsamakas E (2010) Impact of e-book technology: ownership and market asymmetries in digital transformation. Electron Commer Res Appl 9(5):386–399
Katz M, Shapiro C (1986) Technology adoption in the presence of network externalities. J Polit Econ 94(4):822–841
Kim C, Oh E, Shin N (2010) An empirical investigation of digital content characteristics, value, and flow. J Comput Inform Syst 50(4):79–87
Mason George R, Charlotte H (1994) An approach for identifying cannibalization within product line extensions and multi-brand strategies. J Bus Res 31(2–3):163–170
Milliot J, Reid C (2011) It’s a digital book world. Available at http://www.publishersweekly.com/pw/by-topic/digital/conferences/article/45946-it-s-a-digital-book-world.html. Accessed Nov 19 2011
Premkumar GP (2003) Alternate distribution strategies for digital music. Comm ACM 46(9):89–95
Reddy S, Holak S, Bhat S (1994) To extend or not to extend: success determinants of line extensions. J Market Res 31(2):243–262
Reinganum JF (1981) On the diffusion of new technology: a game theoretic approach. Rev Econ Stud 48(3):395–405
Reinganum JF (1981) Market structure and the diffusion of new technology. Bell J Econ 12(2):618–624
Reynolds R (2011) Trends influencing the growth of digital textbooks in US higher education. Publish Res Q 27(2):178–187
Riordan M (1992) Regulation and preemptive technology adoption. Rand J Econ 23(3):334–349
Shapiro C, Varian HR (1999) Information rules: a strategic guide to the network economy. Harvard Business Press, Boston
Smith MD, Telang R (2009) Competing with free: the impact of movie broadcasts on DVD sales and internet piracy. MIS Q 33(2):321–338
Smith MD, Telang R (2010) Piracy or promotion? The impact of broadband Internet penetration on DVD sales. Inform Econ Policy 22(4):289–298
Stenbacka R, Tombak M (1994) Strategic timing of adoption of new technologies under uncertainty. Int J Ind Organ 12(3):387–411
Teece D (1986) Profiting from technological innovation: implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Res Policy 15(6):285–305
Tsay AA, Agrawal N (2004) Channel conflict and coordination in the e-commerce age. Prod Oper Manag 13(1):93–110
Waldfogel J (2009) Lost on the web: does web distribution stimulate or depress television viewing? Inform Econ Policy 21(2):158–168
Yan R, Pei Z (2009) Retail services and firm profit in a dual-channel market. J Retailing Consum Serv 16(4):306–314
Yao DQ, Liu JJ (2005) Competitive pricing of mixed retail and e-tail distribution channels. Omega 33(3):235–247
Yoo WS, Lee E (2011) Internet channel entry: a strategic analysis of mixed channel structures. Market Sci 30(1):29–41
Yue X, Liu J (2006) Demand forecast sharing in a dual-channel supply chain. Eur J Oper Res 174(1):646–667
Zhu K, Weyant J (2003) Strategic decisions of new technology adoption under asymmetric information: a game-theoretic model. Decis Sci 34(4):643–675
Acknowledgments
The authors would like to thank the two Special Issue Guest Editors, Robert Kauffman and Angsana Techatassanasoontorn, and the four anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments and helpful suggestions, which significantly improve the quality of the paper.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix
Appendix
1.1 Proposition 1
Proof
The conditions for Nash equilibrium outcome (I, I) are \( \pi_{A}^{II} > \pi_{A}^{NI} \;{\text{and}}\;\pi_{B}^{II} > \pi_{B}^{IN} . \) That is \( \eta \Uptheta_{N} > C_{A} \;{\text{and}}\;\left( {1 - \eta } \right)\Uptheta_{N} > C_{B} , \) we have \( \Uptheta_{N} > \max \left\{ {C_{A} /\eta , < C_{B} /\left( {1 - \eta } \right)} \right\}. \)
The conditions for Nash equilibrium outcome (I, N) are \( \pi_{A}^{IN} > \pi_{A}^{NN} \;{\text{and}}\;\pi_{B}^{IN} > \pi_{B}^{II} . \) That is \( \Uptheta_{N} - \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} > C_{A} \;{\text{and}}\;\left( {1 - \eta } \right)\Uptheta_{N} < C_{B} ,\) we have \( C_{A} + \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} < \Uptheta_{N} < C_{B} /\left( {1 - \eta } \right). \)
The conditions for Nash equilibrium outcome (N, I) are \( \pi_{A}^{NI} > \pi_{A}^{II} \;{\text{and}}\;\pi_{B}^{NI} > \pi_{B}^{NN} . \) That is \( \eta \Uptheta_{N} < C_{A} \;{\text{and}}\;\Uptheta_{N} - \delta (1 - \alpha )\Uptheta_{T} > C_{B} . \) We have \( C_{B} + \delta (1 - \alpha )\Uptheta_{T} < \Uptheta_{N} < C_{A} /\eta . \)
The conditions for Nash equilibrium outcome (N, N) are \( \pi_{A}^{NN} > \pi_{A}^{IN} \;{\text{and}}\;\pi_{B}^{NN} > \pi_{B}^{NI} . \) That is \( \Uptheta_{N} - \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} < C_{A} \;{\text{and}}\;\Uptheta_{N} - (1 - \alpha )\delta \Uptheta_{T} < C_{B} . \) We have \( \Uptheta_{N} < \min \left\{ {C_{A} + \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} ,C_{B} + \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right\}. \)
1.2 Corollary 1
Proof
The conditions for pure Nash equilibrium adoption strategy \( \left( {\text{I,N}} \right),\;\left( {\text{N,I}} \right) \) are \( C_{A} + \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} < \Uptheta_{N} < C_{B} /\left( {1 - \eta } \right) \) and \( C_{B} + \delta (1 - \alpha )\Uptheta_{T} < \Uptheta_{N} < C_{A} /\eta \) respectively.
Multiple pure Nash equilibra \( \left( {\text{I,N}} \right) ,\left( {\text{N,I}} \right) \) occur when all the above conditions are satisfied or equivalently,
Multiple pure Nash equilibra, \( \left( {\text{I,I}} \right),\;\left( {\text{N,N}} \right) \) occur when all the above conditions are satisfied or equivalently,
1.3 Corollary 2
Proof
The conditions for the existence of mixed Nash adoption strategy is all the conditions in Eq. 9 are not satisfied. \( ( {\text{I, I)}} \) and \( ( {\text{I, N)}} \) will not occur if \( \Uptheta_{N} < \min \left( {C_{A} + \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} ,C_{B} /\left( {1 - \eta } \right)} \right). \) \( ( {\text{N, I)}} \) and \( ( {\text{N, N)}} \) will not occur if \( \Uptheta_{N} > \max \left( {C_{B} + \delta (1 - \alpha )\Uptheta_{T} ,C_{A} /\eta } \right). \) We have
Similarly, the other scenario is \( ( {\text{I, I)}} \) and \( ( {\text{I, N)}} \) will not occur if \( \Uptheta_{N} < \min \left( {C_{B} + \delta (1 - \alpha )\Uptheta_{T} ,C_{A} /\eta } \right). \) \( ( {\text{N, I)}} \) and \( ( {\text{N, N)}} \) will not occur if \( \Uptheta_{N} > \max \left( {C_{A} + \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} ,C_{B} /\left( {1 - \eta } \right)} \right). \) We have \( \max \left( {C_{A} + \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} ,C_{B} /\left( {1 - \eta } \right)} \right) < \Uptheta_{N} < \min \left( {C_{B} + \delta (1 - \alpha )\Uptheta_{T} ,C_{A} /\eta } \right) \).
1.4 Proposition 2
Proof
The mixed strategy Nash equilibrium is described by both Eqs. 16 and 17 are satisfied. We have \( \left( {\gamma_{A}^{*} ,\gamma_{B}^{*} } \right) = \left( {\hat{\gamma }_{A} ,\hat{\gamma }_{B} } \right). \)
1.5 Corollary 3
Proof
(i) From (18), we have \( \partial \gamma_{i}^{*} /\partial C_{i} = 0\quad {\text{for}}\quad i \in \left\{ {A,B} \right\}. \) (ii) \( \partial \gamma_{A}^{*} /\partial C_{B} = \frac{{ - \left( {\eta \Uptheta_{N} - \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right)}}{{\left( {\eta \Uptheta_{N} - \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right)^{2} }} < 0\quad {\text{given}}\quad G_{1} > 0. \) (iii) \( \frac{{\partial r_{B}^{*} }}{{\partial C_{A} }} = \frac{{\alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} - \left( {1 - \eta } \right)\Uptheta_{N} }}{{\left( {\alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} - \left( {1 - \eta } \right)\Uptheta_{N} } \right)^{2} }} > 0 \) when G 2 < 0 (brand extension), but \( \frac{{\partial r_{B}^{*} }}{{\partial C_{A} }} < 0 \) when G 2 > 0 (brand counter-extension).
1.6 Corollary 4
Proof
(i) Since \( 0 \le r_{A}^{*} \le 1, \) we have \( \left( {1 - \eta } \right)\Uptheta_{N} - C_{B} \le 0 \) and \( \frac{{\partial r_{A}^{*} }}{{\partial \left( {\delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right)}} = \frac{{\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)\Uptheta_{N} - C_{B} } \right)}}{{\left( {\eta \theta_{N} - (1 - \alpha )\delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right)^{2} }} \le 0. \) (ii) Since \( 0 \le r_{B}^{*} \le 1 \), we have \( \eta \Uptheta_{N} - C_{A} \le 0 \) when G 2 > 0 and \( \eta \Uptheta_{N} - C_{A} \ge 0 \) when G 2 < 0. Therefore, \( \frac{{\partial r_{B}^{*} }}{{\partial \left( {\delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right)}} = \frac{{\alpha \left( {\eta \Uptheta_{N} - C_{A} } \right)}}{{\left( {\alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} - (1 - \eta )\Uptheta_{N} } \right)^{2} }} \le 0 \) when G 2 > 0 (brand counter-extension) but\( \frac{{\partial r_{B}^{*} }}{{\partial \left( {\delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right)}} \ge 0 \) when G 2 < 0 (brand extension).
1.7 Corollary 5
Proof
(i) Since \( r_{A}^{*} \ge 0 \) and G 1 ≥ 0, we have \( \left( {\Uptheta_{N} - (1 - \alpha )\delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right) - C_{B} \ge 0 \) and \( \frac{{\partial r_{A}^{*} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\Uptheta_{N} \left( {C_{B} + \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\delta \Uptheta_{T} - \Uptheta_{N} } \right)}}{{\left( {\eta \Uptheta_{N} - \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right)^{2} }} \le 0. \) (ii) Since \( r_{B}^{*} \ge 0, \) we have \( \left( {\Uptheta_{N} - \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right) - C_{A} > 0 \) when G 2 > 0 (brand counter-extension) and \( \left( {\Uptheta_{N} - \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right) - C_{A} < 0 \) when G 2 < 0 (brand extension). \( \frac{{\partial r_{B}^{*} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\Uptheta_{N} \left( {\Uptheta_{N} - C_{A} - \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right)}}{{\left( {\alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} - (1 - \eta )\Uptheta_{N} } \right)^{2} }} > 0 \) when G 2 > 0 (brand counter-extension) but \( \frac{{\partial r_{B}^{*} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\Uptheta_{N} \left( {\Uptheta_{N} - C_{A} - \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right)}}{{\left( {\alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} - (1 - \eta )\Uptheta_{N} } \right)^{2} }} < 0 \) when G 2 < 0 (brand extension).
1.8 Proposition 3
Proof
Firm A adopts technology when \( \tilde{C}_{A} \le \hat{C}_{A} . \) Solving Eq. 22, we obtain
The equation \( \tilde{C}_{A} \le \left( {\Uptheta {}_{N} - \alpha \delta \Uptheta {}_{T}} \right) - \Upphi_{B} \left( {\hat{C}_{B} } \right)\left( {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)\Uptheta_{N} - \alpha \delta \Uptheta {}_{T}} \right) = \hat{C}_{A} \) is achieved. Similarly, firm B adopts technology when \( \tilde{C}_{B} \le \hat{C}_{B} . \) Solving Eq. 23, we obtain \( \begin{gathered} \Upphi_{A} \left( {\hat{C}_{A} } \right)\left( {\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( { 1- \delta } \right)\Uptheta_{T} { + }\left( {1 - \eta } \right)\Uptheta_{N} \, - \tilde{C}_{B} } \right) + \left( {1 - \Upphi_{A} \left( {\hat{C}_{A} } \right)} \right)\left( {\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( { 1- \delta } \right)\Uptheta {}_{T} + \Uptheta {}_{N} - \tilde{C}_{B} } \right) \hfill \\ > \Upphi_{A} \left( {\hat{C}_{A} } \right)\left( {\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( { 1- \delta } \right)\Uptheta_{T} } \right) + \left( {1 - \Upphi_{A} \left( {\hat{C}_{A} } \right)} \right)\left( {\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\Uptheta {}_{T}} \right). \hfill \\ \end{gathered} \) We have \( \tilde{C}_{B} \le \left( {\Uptheta {}_{N} - \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\delta \Uptheta {}_{T}} \right) - \Upphi_{B} \left( {\hat{C}_{B} } \right)\left( {\eta \Uptheta_{N} - \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\delta \Uptheta {}_{T}} \right) = \hat{C}_{B} . \)
1.9 Corollary 6
Proof
(A). Under the scenario of brand counter-extension (G 2 > 0), from (24) and (25) we have \( \partial \Upphi_{i} \left( {\hat{C}_{i} } \right)/\partial \hat{C}_{j} < 0 \) and \( \partial \Upphi \left( {\hat{C}_{i} } \right)/\partial \Upphi \left( {\hat{C}_{j} } \right) < 0,\quad i \ne j \in \left\{ {A,B} \right\}. \) \( \Upphi_{i} \left( {\hat{C}_{i} } \right) \) will become lower as the mean of technology cost becomes higher. As a result, \( \Upphi_{j} \left( {\hat{C}_{j} } \right) \) and \( \hat{C}_{j} \) becomes higher and \( \hat{C}_{i} \) becomes smaller.
(B). Under the scenario of brand extension (G 2 < 0), we have \( \partial \Upphi_{A} \left( {\hat{C}_{A} } \right)/\partial \hat{C}_{B} < 0 \) and \( \partial \Upphi_{B} \left( {\hat{C}_{B} } \right)/\partial \hat{C}_{A} > 0 \) No matter whether the equilibrium adoption tendency is high or low, a higher disperse degree (variance) of technology cost may increase or decrease the decision threshold for each firm \( \hat{C}_{i} ,\quad i \in \left\{ {A,B} \right\}. \) Consequently, the impact of cost disperse on the adoption tendency is unclear.
1.9.1 Corollary 7
Proof
(A). Under the scenario of brand counter-extension (G 2 > 0), from (24) and (25) we have \( \partial \Upphi_{i} \left( {\hat{C}_{i} } \right)/\partial \hat{C}_{j} < 0\quad {\text{and}}\quad \partial \Upphi \left( {\hat{C}_{i} } \right)/\partial \Upphi \left( {\hat{C}_{j} } \right) < 0\quad i \ne j \in \left\{ {A,B} \right\}. \) When the equilibrium adoption tendency is low (e.g. \( \hat{C}_{i} < \mu_{i} \)), \( \Upphi_{i} \left( {\hat{C}_{i} } \right) \) will become larger as the disperse degree (variance) of technology cost becomes higher. As a result, \( \Upphi_{j} \left( {\hat{C}_{j} } \right) \) and \( \hat{C}_{j} \) becomes lower and \( \hat{C}_{i} \) becomes larger. On the contrary, if the equilibrium adoption tendency is high (e.g. \( \hat{C}_{i} > \mu_{i} \)), \( \Upphi_{i} \left( {\hat{C}_{i} } \right) \) will become smaller as the disperse degree (variance) of technology cost becomes higher. As a result, \( \Upphi_{j} \left( {\hat{C}_{j} } \right) \) and \( \hat{C}_{j} \) becomes larger and \( \hat{C}_{i} \) becomes smaller.
(B). Under the scenario of brand extension (G 2 < 0), we have \( \partial \Upphi_{A} \left( {\hat{C}_{A} } \right)/\partial \hat{C}_{B} < 0 \) and \( \partial \Upphi_{B} \left( {\hat{C}_{B} } \right)/\partial \hat{C}_{A} > 0. \) No matter the equilibrium adoption tendency is high or low, a higher disperse degree (variance) of technology cost may increase or decrease the decision threshold for each firm \( \hat{C}_{i} ,\quad i \in \left\{ {A,B} \right\}. \) Consequently, the impact of cost disperse on the adoption tendency is unclear.
1.10 Corollary 8
Proof
(i) \( \partial \gamma_{A}^{*} /\partial \Uptheta_{N} = \frac{{\eta C_{B} - \left( {1 - \eta } \right)(1 - \alpha )\delta \Uptheta_{T} }}{{\left( {\eta \Uptheta_{N} - \left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right)^{2} }} > 0, \) given \( 0 \le \gamma_{A}^{*} \le 1\quad {\text{and}}\quad G_{1} > 0. \) Since \( \partial \Uptheta_{N} /\partial \sigma_{D} < 0, \) we have \( \partial \gamma_{A}^{*} /\partial \sigma_{D} < 0. \) (ii) Since \( \frac{{\partial r_{B}^{*} }}{{\partial \Uptheta_{N} }} = \frac{{\left( {1 - \eta } \right)C_{A} - \eta \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} }}{{\left( {\left( {1 - \eta } \right)\Uptheta_{N} - \alpha \delta \Uptheta_{T} } \right)^{2} }} \), we \( \frac{{\partial r_{B}^{*} }}{{\partial \sigma_{D} }} > 0 \) when G 2 < 0 (brand extension), but \( \frac{{\partial r_{B}^{*} }}{{\partial \sigma_{D} }} < 0 \) when G 2 > 0 (brand counter-extension).
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Jin, BH., Li, YM. Analysis of emerging technology adoption for the digital content market. Inf Technol Manag 13, 149–165 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10799-011-0113-6
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10799-011-0113-6