Abstract
The decision of whether or not to vaccinate is a complex one. It involves the contribution both to a social good—herd immunity—and to one’s own well-being. It is informed by social influence, personal experience, education, and mass media. In our work, we investigate a situation in which individuals make their choice based on how social neighbourhood responded to previous epidemics. We do this by proposing a minimalistic model using components from game theory, network theory and the modelling of epidemic spreading, and opinion dynamics. Individuals can use the information about the neighbourhood in two ways—either they follow the majority or the best-performing neighbour. Furthermore, we let individuals learn which of these two decision-making strategies to follow from their experience. Our results show that the flexibility of individuals to choose how to integrate information from the neighbourhood increases the vaccine uptake and decreases the epidemic severity if the following conditions are fulfilled. First, the initial fraction of individuals who imitate the neighbourhood majority should be limited, and second, the memory of previous outbreaks should be sufficiently long. These results have implications for the acceptance of novel vaccines and raising awareness about vaccination, while also pointing to promising future research directions.
Similar content being viewed by others
Avoid common mistakes on your manuscript.
Introduction
The development of vaccines is one of the greatest achievements of modern medicine. They save millions of lives yearly, not only by giving immunity to people exposed to an infection but also by stopping disease outbreaks. Most famously, perhaps, vaccine drove the eradication of smallpox [1]. At the time of writing, vaccines are the main hope for a pharmaceutical solution to the COVID-19 crisis [2,3,4].
To be able to evaluate interventions involving vaccination, we need to model the selection of who gets vaccinated and how that affects epidemics [5]. Creating such models is a very challenging task to which this paper seeks to contribute [6, 7]. The main difficulty lies in the complex feedback mechanisms between the epidemics itself and the decision to get vaccinated [8,9,10]. Not only are there irrational anti-vaccination sentiments that themselves spread through social contagion [11, 12], but sometimes not getting vaccinated is a perfectly rational choice.
When the population level of immunity is high enough, an outbreak will die out by itself. If this is the case, the population is said to have herd immunity. Even if the vaccine is effective, the marginal benefit of getting vaccinated in a society with herd immunity is small [13]. On top of this, a vaccine could be costly, inefficient, laden with side-effects, or inconvenient to administer [14]. For an individual, the reality is often between these extremes and not a choice between a cheap lifesaver or a costly unnecessity. Thus, this choice is known in the literature as the vaccination dilemma [15, 16].
Assume the vaccine is effective but has some side effects (although much milder than the disease itself). Then one can model the rational-choice aspect of vaccination within the framework of game theory [7, 17]. As often is the case, behavioural and economic game theorists both take an interest in this problem, with somewhat different starting points. The behavioural game-theory line of research typically focuses on herd immunity as a public good—something valuable and accessible without competition to anyone in society [9, 10]. Like other public goods, herd immunity is prone to free-riding people who undermine the good by avoiding vaccination [18]. Economic game theorists instead think of vaccination as a decision based on an individual’s costs and benefits, and regard herd immunity as a positive externality. The truth lies in between these pictures [8]. Benefiting a public good is not the most common driving force behind an individual’s vaccination decisions [19, 20]. It would also make little sense to get vaccinated to contribute to herd immunity if very few others were vaccinated, which is precisely when the private benefits are the largest [13]. On the other hand, herd immunity and, ultimately, eradication of a disease are the primary goals at a national level [3, 4], and thus more than a mere externality.
There is a growing research interest in game-theoretic studies of vaccination [6, 17]. For articles in the economic game-theory literature, see, e.g. Geoffard and Philipson [8] or Francis [13] and further references therein. In the evolutionary game-theory literature, early works coupled game theory and epidemic dynamics by differential-equation-based models [21]. Later, authors recognised that social interaction structures are better modelled by networks. For example, in Fu et al. [15] individuals compare their fitness to randomly selected network neighbours to determine whether or not to imitate the neighbour. The phrases “fitness” and “payoff” (that in this paper are synonymous) come from the game-theory literature and capture the ability to avoid infection minus the cost associated with the vaccination. Other authors have extended the use of imitation dynamics. Zhang et al. [22], for example, considered the possibility that decisions are neighbour-dependent by defining an individual’s fitness depending on their entire neighbourhood. Zhang et al. [23] and Han et al. [24] studied individuals with memory, calculating an individual’s fitness as the weighted average of the past payoffs. Moreover, models by Xia et al. [25], Ichinose and Kurisaku [26], and Iwamura and Tanimoto [27] disregarded payoffs altogether in certain situations by allowing individuals to follow the neighbourhood majority with a non-zero probability, or, otherwise, use fitness comparison to decide their action.
Our study extends the above models by unifying two ideas. First, when making a vaccination decision based on the performance of their neighbours, individuals can follow different decision rules. Second, an individual can learn by experience and thus change their decision rule as time goes on. We use two empirically observed decision rules. First, individuals can follow the best performer in the extended neighbourhood (the neighbourhood of a focal node and the node itself) [28, 29]. We call such individuals performists. Second, they can also follow the majority in the extended neighbourhood [28]. We will refer to individuals following this strategy as conformists. Furthermore, we will let the individuals chose between these two rationales based on experience. The duration of the individuals’ memory is one of the model-parameters we explore. In the remainder of this article, we will go over the technical details of our model, present our simulation results, and discuss the broader implications of our findings.
Model description
We construct a network-based epidemiological model with vaccination. The model comprises individuals embedded in a social network through which epidemics spread. Probably the closest scenario is that of seasonal influenza. Occasionally, the population has the opportunity of getting vaccinated. Then individuals evaluate the performance of their social surroundings, and, based on this information, decide about their vaccination. They have two ways (imitation mechanisms) of performing this evaluation—the mentioned conformist and performist strategies. The individuals then update these imitation mechanisms based on experience.
Each cycle of epidemic outbreaks and vaccinations plays out in three stages. First, individuals choose whether or not to vaccinate following their current strategy and available information. Second, we calculate the expectation value of the outbreak size for the particular configuration of vaccinated nodes. This is done by averaging over 640 runs of the Susceptible–Infectious–Recovered (SIR) simulation (discussed further below). Finally, individuals choose between the conformist or performist imitation strategy. We simulate these vaccination cycles over 150 times to reach a steady state.
At the beginning of every simulation, we randomly vaccinate 10 % of the population and let a fraction c be conformists (otherwise performists). From the second vaccination, all individuals make decisions following their strategies. We allow the choice of strategy to depend on the experience gathered through vaccination. We assume that individuals choose the imitation mechanism that gives them a larger average payoff over the period of m preceding vaccination cycles. Memory, therefore, plays a key role in determining whether an individual behaves as a conformist or a performist at any given time during a simulation run.
For the epidemic simulation, we used the standard Markovian Susceptible–Infectious–Recovered (SIR) algorithm [30]. This is the canonical model of diseases that make people immune upon recovery. It has nominally two parameters—the infection rate \(\beta\) and the recovery rate \(\nu\). However, \(\nu\) only sets the time scale of the outbreak, and since we are only interested in the final outbreak size, we can set \(\nu =1\) without loss of generality. We simulate this model with a fast “event-driven algorithm” as described in Kiss et al. [30] and implemented at http://www.github.com/pholme/sir.
When the individuals evaluate their performance, they assume a cost \(c_\mathrm {V}\) per vaccination and a cost \(c_\mathrm {I}\) for getting infected. For an approved vaccine, we can assume \(c_\mathrm {V}<c_\mathrm {I}\). Accordingly, a vaccinated individual receives the payoff \(\Pi _i=-c_\mathrm {V}\) per vaccination cycle, whereas someone who is not vaccinated gets the payoff \(\Pi _i=-c_\mathrm {I} I(i)\), where I(i) is the fraction of outbreak simulations when i got infected. We set \(c_\mathrm {V}=0.1\) and \(c_\mathrm {I} = 1\) throughout our study.
Both conformists and performists make their decisions deterministically. The former follow the majority with probability 1, whereas the latter pursue a larger payoff with probability 1. This means that, in comparison to probabilistic imitation rules (e.g., the Fermi rule), the selection process is stronger, thus converging faster to evolutionary equilibria. Although considering convergence rates may be of some interest when one strategy is only marginally advantageous over the other, this is not the case herein and would require artificial parameter fine-tuning to occur. An added benefit is that finite-size effects disappear at smaller social-network sizes, thus reducing computational requirements.
For underlying interaction topology, we mostly use Erdős–Rényi random graphs with \(N=64\) nodes and equally many edges. We try other, larger, sizes as well, but these give qualitatively similar results. Since this paper will not concern the large-size limit, to cut computation times, we stick with the smaller systems.
We will primarily explore three parameters in our simulations—c, m, and \(\beta\)—and average the simulations described above over \(10^3\) simulation runs. We use the OACIS framework [31] to manage our simulations.
Results
Time evolution. In Fig. 1, we show a representative simulation run of the model. We find that the outbreak size cannot be reduced by having a large initial fraction of conformists, irrespective of the memory length (Fig. 1, yellow curves in a, b). Conversely, if the initial presence of conformists is moderate, the outbreak size is greatly reduced (Fig. 1, blue curves in a, b). Short memory turns out to have almost no effect on the choice of imitation mechanisms, causing the population to end with a similar fraction of conformists as in the initial state (Fig. 1c). Increasing memory changes the situation. In this case, the updating of imitation mechanisms increases, allowing the population to converge to a fraction of conformists noticeably different than in the initial state (Fig. 1d). The population is even able to eliminate outbreaks in the case when the initial fraction of conformists is moderate (Fig. 1, blue curve in panel b). We confirm that the selected simulation run is indeed representative by averaging across a large number of runs (Fig. 2), which exhibit the same qualitative characteristics as the described single run. Note that each single run is realised probabilistically, meaning that, for example, conformism at time \(t=0\) need not be exactly c, but can deviate slightly around this value.
Initial conformism. To further clarify the role of initial conformism, we inspect how the outbreak size depends on the infection rate for various values of the parameter c when memory is relatively long (Fig. 3). At low infection rates, \(\beta \lessapprox 0.5\), the outbreak size is independent of initial conformism. After that, for \(\beta \gtrapprox 0.5\), the results diverge. High initial conformism precipitates massive outbreaks, whereas moderate (\(0.4<c<0.6\)) and low initial conformism prevent them. Interestingly, the outbreak size is smallest when initial conformism hovers around moderate levels of c. The reason why too much conformism leads to a low vaccination coverage is that too many individuals imitate what they see in their neighbourhoods, and they mostly see defection because the starting vaccination coverage is set to 10 %. This particular choice and its implications are further elaborated in the Discussion section.
A detailed examination of the phase space reveals that a population of individuals who dynamically interchange imitation mechanisms, as envisioned in our model, often evolves to moderate levels of conformism, but only if memory is long enough (Fig. 4). The outbreak size is thus reduced in populations with longer memory relative to those with shorter memory, for all infection rates \(\beta \gtrapprox 0.5\) and irrespective of initial conformism (Fig. 4a, b). The reason for this reduction is that individuals who keep a shorter track of the past tend to stick to a single imitation mechanism, impeding the evolution of conformism towards moderate levels that help curb the disease (Fig. 4c). Conversely, individuals who keep a longer track of the past see their population evolve towards the disease-curbing, moderate levels of conformism between 40 and 60 % over a wide area of the phase space, that is, for \(\beta \gtrapprox 0.5\) and \(0.10\lessapprox c\lessapprox 0.85\) (Fig. 4d).
Memory length. Our results so far have suggested that memory length plays a vital role in shaping the fate of disease outbreaks. We now inspect this role in further detail. In particular, looking at how the population performs as the memory length increases, we find that long memory is better than short, even in situations when initial conformism is in the disease-curbing, moderate range (Fig. 5). The effect is even more pronounced when initial conformism is outside of the moderate range (Fig. 6a), the reason being that long memory, characterised by \(m>4\), entices a substantial dynamical interchange of imitation rules when the infection rate is sufficiently large (\(\beta \gtrapprox 0.5\)), thus driving the level of conformism to evolve to moderate values between 40 and 60 % (Fig. 6c). Short memory, characterised by \(m<3\), cannot achieve the same as initial conformism is largely preserved throughout simulation runs (Fig. 6c). That moderate conformism indeed curbs the disease effectively is revealed by simulation runs for \(c=0.5\) because in this case, the outbreak size (Fig. 6b) is always small, while the final level of conformism is still between 40 and 60 % (Fig. 6d), independent of the infection rate and the memory length.
An alternative way to understand our results is in terms of the basic reproduction number, \(R_0\), and its effective counterpart, \(R_\mathrm {e}\). In the model, vaccination makes a certain fraction of individuals immune even before the onset of an epidemic. The effective reproduction number is therefore right from the start \(R_\mathrm {e}=R_0(1-\mathrm {VC})\), where \(\mathrm {VC}\) stands for the vaccination coverage. Although the case of \(\beta =0.5\) has a lower \(R_0\) value than the case of, say, \(\beta =3\), the epidemic is felt much more strongly in the latter case, and consequently, the evolutionary dynamics drives the population to embrace vaccination (giving rise to a much larger \(\mathrm {VC}\)). The end result is that the effective reproduction number, as well as the outbreak size, is much lower for \(\beta =3\) than \(\beta =0.5\).
Network structure. To confirm that the described results are robust to the choice of network structure, we have run additional simulations on two-dimensional square lattices and scale-free networks. Interestingly, only the former structure exhibits any noteworthy differences compared to the Erdős–Rényi networks. Our previous observation that a longer memory length reduces the outbreak size as the infection rate increases is valid for all networks structures (Fig. 7a, b). The square lattice quantitatively differs from the Erdős–Rényi network in that the former has a much larger diameter which, for a given infection rate, impedes disease outbreaks. This, in turn, somewhat weakens the effect of long memory on suppressing diseases. Indeed, a longer memory always leads to more vaccination coverage, but such coverage is much smaller in the lattice than in the Erdős–Rényi network when infection rates are relatively large (Fig. 7c, d). Individuals thus have an easier time learning the best course of action to combat epidemics in tighter, more compact networks.
Discussion
We have constructed a model of vaccination—based in equal proportions on game theory, network epidemiology, and models of social influence—in which individuals in addition to deciding whether to vaccinate or not, also have the option to choose a preferred imitation mechanism. Individuals called conformists thus rely on a simple heuristic by which they imitate the behaviour of the neighbourhood majority. Performists, by contrast, imitate neighbours that perform the best in terms of payoff. The results show that the dynamic interchange of these imitation mechanisms suppresses disease outbreaks through better vaccination. Two notable phenomena are that (i) too much initial conformism in the population and (ii) short memory of individuals are obstructive for the vaccination coverage.
As mentioned before, the reason why too much conformism leads to a low vaccination coverage is that too many individuals imitate what they see in their neighbourhoods, and they mostly see defection. This, in turn, is because our simulations start with the initial vaccination coverage of 10 %, which is a valid starting point from the perspective of novel vaccine acceptance. Such an angle is relevant at the time of writing. On the one hand, we are amidst a pandemic (COVID-19) for which vaccines seem like the best hope for a solution [2,3,4]. On the other hand, recent years have seen a trend of increasing vaccine hesitancy [10, 20, 32]. This trend could partly be explained by the kind of mix of rational thinking and predisposition to following the crowd as is manifested by the conformists [11, 33]. However, probably it would be more appropriate to extend our model to include zealots—individuals who do not let the dynamics of the game to affect their choices [14, 18].
The other notable phenomenon revealed by our model, specifically, that more extended memory helps boost the vaccination coverage, is suggestive in the sense that educational measures could be used to bolster the collective awareness of the role of vaccines in controlling infectious diseases [19]. Classrooms are an ideal setting to raise awareness about the burden of infectious diseases as well as the success of vaccines in limiting these [1, 34]. An immediate reason for suggesting measures to bolster collective awareness is that past events tend to be entirely forgotten, or at least, their perceived importance diminishes with the passage of time. The model could account for the effects of human forgetfulness by adding weights to memory such that more distant past decisions contribute less to present decisions. The suggested educational measures would then have the effect of keeping the weights larger overall. A difficulty with this approach is a lack of basis for assigning concrete numerical values to the weights, which perhaps could be overcome by means of behavioural experiments.
Finally, we note that in our simulations, the individuals learn strategies to make the vaccination choice. This means they are manifesting “wisdom of crowds” [35]—i.e., that populations can perform distributed computation tasks, integrating information without central control.
References
Henderson, D. A. (2009). Smallpox: The death of a disease. Buffalo: Prometheus Books.
Lurie, N., Saville, M., Hatchett, R., & Halton, J. (2020). Developing Covid-19 vaccines at pandemic speed. The New England Journal of Medicine, 382, 1969.
Corey, L., Mascola, J. R., Fauci, A. S., & Collins, F. S. (2020). A strategic approach to COVID-19 vaccine R&D. Science, 368, 948.
Graham, B. S. (2020). Rapid COVID-19 vaccine development. Science, 368, 945.
Hufnagel, L., Brockmann, D., & Geisel, T. (2004). Forecast and control of epidemics in a globalized world. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 101, 15124.
Wang, Z., Andrews, M. A., Wu, Z.-X., Wang, L., & Bauch, C. T. (2015). Coupled disease-behavior dynamics on complex networks: A review. Physics of Life Reviews, 15, 1.
Wang, Z., Bauch, C. T., Bhattacharyya, S., d’Onofrio, A., Manfredi, P., Perc, M., et al. (2016). Statistical physics of vaccination. Physics Reports, 664, 1.
Geoffard, P.-Y., & Philipson, T. (1997). Disease eradication: Private versus public vaccination. American Economic Review, 87, 222.
Chapman, G. B., Li, M., Vietri, J., Ibuka, Y., Thomas, D., Yoon, H., et al. (2012). Using game theory to examine incentives in influenza vaccination behavior. Psychological Science, 23, 1008.
Ibuka, Y., Li, M., Vietri, J., Chapman, G. B., & Galvani, A. P. (2014). Free-riding behavior in vaccination decisions: An experimental study. PLOS One, 9, 0087164.
Jolley, D., & Douglas, K. M. (2014). The effects of anti-vaccine conspiracy theories on vaccination intentions. PLOS One, 9, e89177.
Saint-Victor, D. S., & Omer, S. B. (2013). Vaccine refusal and the endgame: walking the last mile first. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B, 368, 20120148.
Francis, P. J. (1997). Dynamic epidemiology and the market for vaccinations. Journal of Public Economics, 63, 383.
Verelst, F., Willem, L., Kessels, R., & Beutels, P. (2018). Individual decisions to vaccinate one’s child or oneself: A discrete choice experiment rejecting free-riding motives. Social Science and Medicine, 207, 106.
Fu, F., Rosenbloom, D. I., Wang, L., & Nowak, M. A. (2011). Imitation dynamics of vaccination behaviour on social networks. Proceedings of the Royal Society B, 278, 42.
Cardillo, A., Reyes-Suárez, C., Naranjo, F., & Gómez-Gardenes, J. (2013). Evolutionary vaccination dilemma in complex networks. Physical Review E, 88, 032803.
Chang, S. L., Piraveenan, M., Pattison, P., & Prokopenko, M. (2020). Game theoretic modelling of infectious disease dynamics and intervention methods: A review. Journal of Biological Dynamics, 14, 57.
Coleman, J. S. (1988). Free riders and zealots: The role of social networks. Social Theory, 6, 52.
Betsch, C., Böhm, R., & Chapman, G. B. (2015). Using behavioral insights to increase vaccination policy effectiveness. Policy Insights from the Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 2, 61.
Salmon, D. A., Dudley, M. Z., Glanz, J. M., & Omer, S. B. (2015). Vaccine hesitancy: Causes, consequences, and a call to action. Vaccine, 33, D66.
Bauch, C. T., & Earn, D. J. D. (2004). Vaccination and the theory of games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 101, 13391.
Zhang, Y. (2013). The impact of other-regarding tendencies on the spatial vaccination game. Chaos Solitons and Fractals, 56, 209.
Zhang, H., Fu, F., Zhang, W., & Wang, B. (2012). Rational behavior is a ‘double-edged sword’ when considering voluntary vaccination. Physica A, 391, 4807.
Han, D., & Sun, M. (2014). Can memory and conformism resolve the vaccination dilemma? Physica A, 415, 95.
Xia, S., & Liu, J. (2013). A computational approach to characterizing the impact of social influence on individuals’ vaccination decision making. PLOS One, 8, e60373.
Ichinose, G., & Kurisaku, T. (2017). Positive and negative effects of social impact on evolutionary vaccination game in networks. Physica A, 468, 84.
Iwamura, Y., & Tanimoto, J. (2018). Realistic decision-making processes in a vaccination game. Physica A, 494, 236.
Traulsen, A., Semmann, D., Sommerfeld, R. D., Krambeck, H.-J., & Milinski, M. (2010). Human strategy updating in evolutionary games. Proceedings of the Natioinal Academy of Sciences, 107, 2962.
Grujić, J., & Lenaerts, T. (2020). Do people imitate when making decisions? Evidence from a spatial prisoner’s dilemma experiment. Royal Society Open Science, 7, 200618.
Kiss, I. Z., Miller, J. C., & Simon, P. L. (2017). Mathematics of epidemics on networks. New York: Springer.
Murase, Y., Uchitane, T., & Ito, N. (2017). An open-source job management framework for parameter-space exploration: OACIS. Journal of Physics: Conference Series, 921, 012001.
Dubé, E., Laberge, C., Guay, M., Bramadat, P., Roy, R., & Bettinger, J. A. (2013). Vaccine hesitancy: an overview. Human Vaccines and Immunotherapeutics, 9, 1763.
Berinsky, A. J. (2017). Rumors and health care reform: Experiments in political misinformation. British Journal of Political Science, 47, 241.
S. W. Roush, T. V. Murphy, V.-P. D. T. W. Group, et al. Historical comparisons of morbidity and mortality for vaccinepreventable diseases in the United States. JAMA 298, 2155(2007).
Surowiecki, J. (2005). The wisdom of crowds. New York: Anchor.
Acknowledgements
The authors appreciate financial support from JSPS KAKENHI grants no. JP 18H01655 and JP 20H04288. JSPS stands for the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Contributions
M. J. and P. H. devised research. S. M. performed research. All authors discussed the results and wrote the manuscript.
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Conflict of interest
Authors declare no conflict of interest.
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Miyoshi, S., Jusup, M. & Holme, P. Flexible imitation suppresses epidemics through better vaccination. J Comput Soc Sc 4, 709–720 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s42001-021-00105-z
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s42001-021-00105-z