Abstract
To improve the consumer shopping experience and to remain competitive, an increasing number of retailers continue to increase their investment in technology services and actively seek help from technology service providers to transform and upgrade their retail business. Technology service providers deliver new technological solutions for retailers by providing professional retailing technology services (e.g., building omnichannel retailing modes). Considering this context, we seek to understand whether retailers expect to use technology services and service providers’ expectations of providing retailing services. In this paper, we build a two-tier supply chain with one upstream technology service provider and one downstream retailer (or two competitive retailers) to analyse the strategic choice of the retailer(s) and the service provider. We find that the retailer(s) can purchase a professional retailing technology from the technology service provider and that the service provider is willing to provide technology to two competing retailers, which can increase market demand and yield higher profits. Furthermore, we find the impact of the technological contribution level, retail competition intensity, the power structure, and the technology marketing effect on decision outcomes is significant. Therefore, retailers should consider the influence of these factors when service providers deliver a retailing technology service.
Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
Source: http://www.bizcent.com/.
Source: https://www.deepblueai.com/.
Notably, the technological contribution level indicates the level of the technological contributions made by the technology service provider to deliver the omnichannel service or chain store service in the supply chain. In our model, the technological contribution level is shown in formula (2).
Technology marketing effect measures marginal demand with respect to the technology output level by technology marketing, which indicates the influence of the retailer’s technology marketing on demand.
References
Priporas, C. V., Stylos, N., & Fotiadis, A. K. (2017). Generation Z consumers’ expectations of interactions in smart retailing: A future agenda. Computers in Human Behavior, 77, 374–381.
Zhitomirsky-Geffet, M., & Blau, M. (2016). Cross-generational analysis of predictive factors of addictive behavior in smartphone usage. Computers in Human Behavior, 64, 682–693.
Halilovic, S., & Cicic, M. (2013). Antecedents of information systems user behavior-extended expectation-confirmation model. Behaviour & Information Technology, 32(4), 359–370.
Pantano, E., & Viassone, M. (2015). Engaging consumers on new integrated multichannel retail settings: Challenges for retailers. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Service, 25, 106–114.
Pantano, E., & Priporas, C. V. (2016). The effect of mobile retailing on consumers’ purchasing experiences: A dynamic perspective. Computers in Human Behavior, 61, 548–555.
Oliveira, T., Thomas, M., Baptista, G., & Campos, F. (2016). Mobile payment: Understanding the determinants of customer adoption and intention to recommend the technology. Computers in Human Behavior, 61, 404–414.
Liu, J., Kauffman, R. J., & Ma, D. (2015). Competition, cooperation, and regulation: Understanding the evolution of the mobile payments technology ecosystem. Electronic Commerce Research and Applications, 14(5), 372–391.
Hedman, J., & Henningsson, S. (2015). The new normal: Market cooperation in the mobile payments ecosystem. Electronic Commerce Research and Applications, 14(5), 305–318.
Evanschitzky, H., Iyer, G. R., Pillai, K. G., Kenning, P., & Schütte, R. (2015). Consumer trial, continuous use, and economic benefits of a retail service innovation: The case of the personal shopping assistant. Journal of Product Innovation Management, 32(3), 459–475.
Roy, S. K., Balaji, M. S., Sadeque, S., Nguyen, B., & Melewar, T. C. (2017). Constituents and consequences of smart customer experience in retailing. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 124, 257–270.
Balaji, M. S., & Roy, S. K. (2017). Value co-creation with Internet of things technology in the retail industry. Journal of Marketing Management, 33(1–2), 7–31.
Huang, T. L. (2019). Psychological mechanisms of brand love and information technology identity in virtual retail environments. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Service, 47, 251–264.
Pantano, E., & Vannucci, V. (2019). Who is innovating? An exploratory research of digital technologies diffusion in retail industry. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Service, 49, 297–304.
Pantano, E., & Timmermans, H. (2014). What is smart for retailing? Procedia Environmental Sciences, 22, 101–107.
Varadarajan, R., Srinivasan, R., Vadakkepatt, G. G., Yadav, M. S., Pavlou, P. A., Krishnamurthy, S., et al. (2010). Interactive technologies and retailing strategy: A review, conceptual framework and future research directions. Journal of Interactive Marketing, 24(2), 96–110.
Chen, J. S., & Tsou, H. T. (2012). Performance effects of IT capability, service process innovation, and the mediating role of customer service. Journal of Engineering and Technology Management, 29(1), 71–94.
Handley, S. M., de Jong, J., & Benton, W. C., Jr. (2019). How service provider dependence perceptions moderate the power-opportunism relationship with professional service. Production and Operations Management, 28(7), 1692–1715.
Willems, K., Smolders, A., Brengman, M., Luyten, K., & Schöning, J. (2017). The path-to-purchase is paved with digital opportunities: An inventory of shopper-oriented retail technologies. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 124, 228–242.
Pantano, E., & Di Pietro, L. (2012). Understanding consumer’s acceptance of technology-based innovations in retailing. Journal of Technology Management & Innovation, 7(4), 1–19.
Zhu, Z., Nakata, C., Sivakumar, K., & Grewal, D. (2013). Fix it or leave it? Customer recovery from self-service technology failures. Journal of Retailing, 89(1), 15–29.
Pantano, E. (2014). Innovation management in retailing: From consumer perspective to corporate strategy. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Service, 21(5), 825–826.
Renko, S., & Druzijanic, M. (2014). Perceived usefulness of innovative technology in retailing: Consumers׳ and retailers׳ point of view. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Service, 21(5), 836–843.
Bharadwaj, N., Naylor, R. W., & Ter Hofstede, F. (2009). Consumer response to and choice of customized versus standardized systems. International Journal of Research in Marketing, 26(3), 216–227.
Newsom, M. K., Collier, D. A., & Olsen, E. O. (2009). Using “biztainment” to gain competitive advantage. Business Horizons, 52(2), 167–176.
Sorescu, A., Frambach, R. T., Singh, J., Rangaswamy, A., & Bridges, C. (2011). Innovations in retail business models. Journal of Retailing, 87, S3–S16.
Yoo, W. S., & Lee, E. (2011). Internet channel entry: A strategic analysis of mixed channel structures. Marketing Science, 30(1), 29–41.
Zhuang, H., Leszczyc, P. T. P., & Lin, Y. (2018). Why is price dispersion higher online than offline? The impact of retailer type and shopping risk on price dispersion. Journal of Retailing, 94(2), 136–153.
Tsay, A. A., & Agrawal, N. (2004). Channel conflict and coordination in the e-commerce age. Production and Operations Management, 13(1), 93–110.
Geng, Q., & Mallik, S. (2007). Inventory competition and allocation in a multi-channel distribution system. European Journal of Operational Research, 182(2), 704–729.
Cai, G. G. (2010). Channel selection and coordination in dual-channel supply chains. Journal of Retailing, 86(1), 22–36.
Liu, Q., & Zhang, D. (2013). Dynamic pricing competition with strategic customers under vertical product differentiation. Management Science, 59(1), 84–101.
Wu, L., Deng, S., & Jiang, X. (2018). Sampling and pricing strategy under competition. Omega-The International Journal of Management Science, 80, 192–208.
Chen, P., Zhao, R., Yan, Y., & Li, X. (2019). Promotional Pricing and Online Business Model Choice in the Presence of Retail Competition. Omega-The International Journal of Management Science. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.omega.2019.07.001.
Chen, L. G., Ding, D., & Ou, J. (2014). Power structure and profitability in assembly supply chains. Production and Operations Management, 23(9), 1599–1616.
Luo, Z., Chen, X., & Kai, M. (2018). The effect of customer value and power structure on retail supply chain product choice and pricing decisions. Omega-The International Journal of Management Science, 77, 115–126.
Perrons, R. K. (2009). The open kimono: How Intel balances trust and power to maintain platform leadership. Research Policy, 38(8), 1300–1312.
Gassmann, O., Enkel, E., & Chesbrough, H. (2010). The future of open innovation. R&d Management, 40(3), 213–221.
Ge, Z., Hu, Q., & Xia, Y. (2014). Firms’ R&D cooperation behavior in a supply chain. Production and Operations Management, 23(4), 599–609.
Yenipazarli, A. (2017). To collaborate or not to collaborate: Prompting upstream eco-efficient innovation in a supply chain. European Journal of Operational Research, 260(2), 571–587.
Chen, X., Wang, X., & Zhou, M. (2019). Firms’ green R&D cooperation behaviour in a supply chain: Technological spillover, power and coordination. International Journal of Production Economics, 218, 118–134.
Zhu, W., & He, Y. (2017). Green product design in supply chains under competition. European Journal of Operational Research, 258(1), 165–180.
D’Aspremont, C., & Jacquemin, A. (1988). Cooperative and noncooperative R & D in duopoly with spillovers. The American Economic Review, 78(5), 1133–1137.
Chen, R. R., & Roma, P. (2011). Group buying of competing retailers. Production and Operations Management, 20(2), 181–197.
Tian, L., Vakharia, A. J., Tan, Y., & Xu, Y. (2018). Marketplace, Reseller, or Hybrid: Strategic Analysis of an Emerging E-Commerce Model. Production and Operations Management, 27(8), 1595–1610.
Petrescu, R. V. (2019). Face Recognition as a Biometric Application. Journal of Mechatronics and Robotics, 3, 237–257.
Liu, B., Cai, G., & Tsay, A. A. (2014). Advertising in asymmetric competing supply chains. Production and Operations Management, 23(11), 1845–1858.
Gupta, S. (2008). Channel structure with knowledge spillovers. Marketing Science, 27(2), 247–261.
Roy, S. K., Balaji, M. S., Quazi, A., & Quaddus, M. (2018). Predictors of customer acceptance of and resistance to smart technologies in the retail sector. Journal of Retailing and Consumer Service, 42, 147–160.
Ma, P., Wang, H., & Shang, J. (2013). Supply chain channel strategies with quality and marketing effort-dependent demand. International Journal of Production Economics, 144(2), 572–581.
Song, J., Li, F., Wu, D. D., Liang, L., & Dolgui, A. (2017). Supply chain coordination through integration of innovation effort and advertising support. Applied Mathematical Modelling, 49, 108–123.
Rosenbaum, M. S., & Wong, I. A. (2015). If you install it, will they use it? Understanding why hospitality customers take “technological pauses” from self-service technology. Journal of Business Research, 68(9), 1862–1868.
Kwee-Meier, S. T., Bützler, J. E., & Schlick, C. (2016). Development and validation of a technology acceptance model for safety-enhancing, wearable locating systems. Behaviour & Information Technology, 35(5), 394–409.
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1992). Advances in prospect theory: Cumulative representation of uncertainty. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5(4), 297–323.
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (2013). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. In Handbook of the Fundamentals of Financial Decision Making, Part I: 99–127.
Acknowledgements
First, the authors would like to thank the anonymous reviewers and the editors for their constructive comments on an earlier version of the paper. Second, the research described in this paper was significantly supported by the Postdoctoral Research Foundation of China (No. 2019M652682), the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (No. CCNU20QN016), and the Hubei Province Postdoctoral Science and Technology Activity Project (No. 2018Z37).
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Additional information
Publisher's Note
Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendix
Appendix
Proof of Proposition 1
According to the equilibrium solutions of Lemmas 1 and 2, we use derivation rule to obtain the results of proposition 1. We omit the straightforward algebraic steps here.\(\square\)
Proof of Proposition 2
-
(1)
PBC mode
According to Lemma 2, we have
Further, we obtain \(\frac{{\partial p_{i}^{PBC} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\partial p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PBC} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{2\alpha \gamma (\beta^{2} - \gamma )}}{{\left[ {2\gamma (2 + \eta ) - \beta^{2} (1 + \eta )} \right]^{2} }} = \frac{{2\alpha \gamma^{2} (G - 1)}}{{\left[ {2\gamma (2 + \eta ) - \beta^{2} (1 + \eta )} \right]^{2} }}\), and \(G = \frac{{\beta^{2} }}{\gamma }\). Thus, when \(0 < G < 1\), we have \(\frac{{\partial p_{i}^{PBC} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\partial p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PBC} }}{\partial \eta } < 0\); when \(1 < G < \frac{2(2 + \eta )}{1 + \eta }\), we have \(\frac{{\partial p_{i}^{PBC} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\partial p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PBC} }}{\partial \eta } > 0\).
-
(2)
PNC mode
Under the PNC mode, we have \(\frac{{\partial w^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{2\alpha \gamma \beta^{2} }}{{\left[ {4\gamma - A\beta^{2} } \right]^{2} }}\frac{\partial A}{\partial \eta }\), and \(\frac{\partial A}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{32 + 144\eta + 232\eta^{2} + 160\eta^{3} + 44\eta^{4} }}{{\left[ {4(1 + \eta )(2 + 4\eta + \eta^{2} )} \right]^{2} }} > 0\), we let \(\frac{\partial A}{\partial \eta } = A_{1}\), obtain \(\frac{{\partial w^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{2A_{1} \alpha \gamma \beta^{2} }}{{\left[ {4\gamma - A\beta^{2} } \right]^{2} }} > 0\), and \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{S} (PNC )}}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{4A_{1} \alpha^{2} \gamma^{2} }}{{\left[ {4\gamma - A\beta^{2} } \right]^{2} }} > 0\), \(\frac{{\partial \theta^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{4A_{1} \alpha \gamma \beta }}{{\left[ {4\gamma - A\beta^{2} } \right]^{2} }} > 0\), \(\frac{{\partial Q_{i}^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } > 0\), \(\frac{{\partial Q_{j ,j \ne i}^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } > 0\).
Further, we have \(\frac{{\partial p_{i}^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{A_{2} \alpha \gamma^{2} \left( {G - \frac{{8 + 16\eta + 12\eta^{2} }}{{A_{2} }}} \right)}}{{\left[ {(2 + 4\eta + \eta^{2} )(4\gamma - A\beta^{2} )} \right]^{2} }}\), and \(A_{2} = (6 + 11\eta + 2\eta^{2} )(2 + 4\eta + \eta^{2} )A_{1} + (2 + 4\eta + 3\eta^{2} )A\). Thus, when \(0 < G < \frac{{8 + 16\eta + 12\eta^{2} }}{{A_{2} }}\), we obtain \(\frac{{\partial p_{i}^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } < 0\); when \(\frac{{8 + 16\eta + 12\eta^{2} }}{{A_{2} }} < G < \frac{4}{A}\), we obtain \(\frac{{\partial p_{i}^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } > 0\).
Similarly, we have
\(A_{3} = (12 + 34\eta + 25\eta^{2} + 4\eta^{3} )(4 + 12\eta + 10\eta^{2} + 2\eta^{3} )A_{1} + (8 + 40\eta + 64\eta^{2} + 40\eta^{3} + 10\eta^{4} )A\).
Thus, when \(0 < G < \frac{{32 + 160\eta + 256\eta^{2} + 160\eta^{3} + 40\eta^{4} }}{{A_{3} }}\), we obtain \(\frac{{\partial p_{j .j \ne i}^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } < 0\); when \(\frac{{32 + 160\eta + 256\eta^{2} + 160\eta^{3} + 40\eta^{4} }}{{A_{3} }} < G < \frac{4}{A}\), we obtain \(\frac{{\partial p_{j .j \ne i}^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } > 0\). In summary, when \(\hbox{max} G < G < \frac{2(2 + \eta )}{1 + \eta }\),we have \(\frac{{\partial p_{i}^{PBC} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\partial p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PBC} }}{\partial \eta } > 0\), \(\frac{{\partial p_{i}^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } > 0\), \(\frac{{\partial p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } > 0\); when \(0 < G < \hbox{min} G_{1}\), we have \(\frac{{\partial p_{i}^{PBC} }}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\partial p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PBC} }}{\partial \eta } < 0\), \(\frac{{\partial p_{i}^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } < 0\), \(\frac{{\partial p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PNC} }}{\partial \eta } < 0\), \(\hbox{max} G_{1} = \hbox{max} \left\{ {1 ,\frac{{8 + 16\eta + 12\eta^{2} }}{{A_{2} }} ,\frac{{32 + 160\eta + 256\eta^{2} + 160\eta^{3} + 40\eta^{4} }}{{A_{3} }}} \right\}\), \(\hbox{min} G_{1} = \hbox{min} \left\{ {1 ,\frac{{8 + 16\eta + 12\eta^{2} }}{{A_{2} }} ,\frac{{32 + 160\eta + 256\eta^{2} + 160\eta^{3} + 40\eta^{4} }}{{A_{3} }}} \right\}\), \(A_{1} = \frac{{32 + 144\eta + 232\eta^{2} + 160\eta^{3} + 44\eta^{4} }}{{\left[ {4(1 + \eta )(2 + 4\eta + \eta^{2} )} \right]^{2} }}\), \(A_{2} = (6 + 11\eta + 2\eta^{2} )(2 + 4\eta + \eta^{2} )A_{1} + (2 + 4\eta + 3\eta^{2} )A\), \(A_{3} = (12 + 34\eta + 25\eta^{2} + 4\eta^{3} )(4 + 12\eta + 10\eta^{2} + 2\eta^{3} )A_{1} + (8 + 40\eta + 64\eta^{2} + 40\eta^{3} + 10\eta^{4} )A\). \(\square\)
Proof of Proposition 3
-
(1)
PBC mode
According to Lemma 2, we have \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{S} (PBC )}}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{2\alpha^{2} \gamma^{2} }}{{\left[ {2\gamma (2 + \eta ) - \beta^{2} (1 + \eta )} \right]^{2} }} > 0\), \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC)}}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PBC)}}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\alpha^{2} \gamma^{3} (1 + \eta )\left( {G - \frac{2\eta }{1 + \eta }} \right)}}{{\left[ {2\gamma (2 + \eta ) - \beta^{2} (1 + \eta )} \right]^{3} }}\). Thus, when \(0 < G < \frac{2\eta }{1 + \eta }\), we obtain \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC)}}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PBC)}}{\partial \eta } < 0\); when \(\frac{2\eta }{1 + \eta } < G < \frac{2(2 + \eta )}{1 + \eta }\), we obtain \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC)}}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PBC)}}{\partial \eta } > 0\).
-
(2)
PNC Mode
Under the PNC mode, we have \(\frac{\partial A}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{32 + 144\eta + 232\eta^{2} + 160\eta^{3} + 44\eta^{4} }}{{\left[ {4(1 + \eta )(2 + 4\eta + \eta^{2} )} \right]^{2} }} > 0\), \(\frac{\partial A}{\partial \eta } = A_{1}\), thus \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{S} (PNC )}}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{4A_{1} \alpha^{2} \gamma^{2} }}{{\left[ {4\gamma - A\beta^{2} } \right]^{2} }} > 0\). Further, we have
Thus, when \(0 < G < \frac{{4A_{4} }}{{AA_{4} + A_{5} }}\), we obtain \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PNC)}}{\partial \eta } < 0\); when \(\frac{{4A_{4} }}{{AA_{4} + A_{5} }} < G < \frac{4}{A}\), we obtain \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PNC)}}{\partial \eta } > 0\).
Similarly, we have
Thus, when \(0 < G < \frac{{4(A_{7} + A_{8} - A_{6} )}}{{A(A_{7} + A_{8} - A_{6} ) + A_{9} }}\), we obtain \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PNC)}}{\partial \eta } < 0\); when \(\frac{{4(A_{7} + A_{8} - A_{6} )}}{{A(A_{7} + A_{8} - A_{6} ) + A_{9} }} < G < \frac{4}{A}\), we obtain \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PNC)}}{\partial \eta } > 0\). In summary, when \(0 < G < \hbox{min} G_{2}\), we have \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{i} }}^{{}} (PBC)}}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }}^{{}} (PBC)}}{\partial \eta } < 0\), \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{i} }}^{{}} (PNC)}}{\partial \eta } < 0\), \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }}^{{}} (PNC)}}{\partial \eta } < 0\); when \(\hbox{max} G_{2} < G < \frac{2(2 + \eta )}{1 + \eta }\), we have \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{i} }}^{{}} (PBC)}}{\partial \eta } = \frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }}^{{}} (PBC)}}{\partial \eta } > 0\), \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{i} }}^{{}} (PNC)}}{\partial \eta } > 0\), \(\frac{{\partial \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }}^{{}} (PNC)}}{\partial \eta } > 0\), \(\hbox{min} G_{2} = \hbox{min} \left\{ {\frac{2\eta }{1 + \eta },\frac{{4A_{4} }}{{AA_{4} + A_{5} }},\frac{{4(A_{7} + A_{8} - A_{6} )}}{{A(A_{7} + A_{8} - A_{6} ) + A_{9} }}} \right\}\), \(\hbox{max} G_{2} = \hbox{max} \left\{ {\frac{2\eta }{1 + \eta },\frac{{4A_{4} }}{{AA_{4} + A_{5} }},\frac{{4(A_{7} + A_{8} - A_{6} )}}{{A(A_{7} + A_{8} - A_{6} ) + A_{9} }}} \right\}\).\(\square\)
Proof of Proposition 4
-
(1)
Comparison of \(w^{C}\) and \(w^{M}\)
According to Lemmas 1 and 2, under the PBC mode, we have
Under the PNC mode, we have
Since \(A = \frac{{8 + 28\eta + 29\eta^{2} + 8\eta^{3} }}{{4(1 + \eta )\left( {2 + 4\eta + \eta^{2} } \right)^{{}} }}\), we have \(A - 1 > 0\), thus \(w^{PNC} - w^{M} > 0\). Further, we obtain
Since \(2(1 + \eta ) - A(2 + \eta ) > 0\), we have \(w^{PBC} - w^{PNC} > 0\), that is \(w^{PBC} > w^{PNC}\).
-
(2)
Comparison of \(\theta^{C}\) and \(\theta^{M}\)
Under the PBC mode, we have
Under the PNC mode, we have
Further, we obtain
Since \(4(1 + \eta ) - 2A(2 + \eta ) > 0\), we have \(\theta^{PBC} - \theta^{PNC} > 0\), that is \(\theta^{PBC} > \theta^{PNC}\).
-
(3)
Comparison of \(Q^{C}\) and \(Q^{M}\)
According to Lemmas 1 and 2, under the PBC mode, we have
By the same calculation, we obtain \(Q^{PNC}\) is greater than \(Q^{M}\) under the PNC mode.
-
(4)
Comparison of \(p_{i}^{C}\) and \(P^{M}\), \(p_{j ,j \ne i}^{C}\) and \(P^{M}\)
Under the PBC mode, we have
Thus, when \(0 < G < 1\), we obtain \(p_{i}^{PBC} = p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PBC} < P^{M}\); when \(1 < G < \frac{2(2 + \eta )}{1 + \eta }\), we obtain \(p_{i}^{PBC} = p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PBC} > P^{M}\).
Under the PNC mode, we have
\(A_{10} = (A - 1)(6 + 11\eta + 2\eta^{2} ) + A(\eta + \eta^{2} )\). Thus, when \(0 < G < \frac{{4(\eta + \eta^{2} )}}{{A_{10} }}\), we obtain \(p_{i}^{PNC} < P^{M}\); when \(\frac{{4(\eta + \eta^{2} )}}{{A_{10} }} < G < \frac{4}{A}\), we obtain \(p_{i}^{PNC} > P^{M}\).
\(A_{11} = (A - 1)(12 + 34\eta + 25\eta^{2} + 4\eta^{3} ) + A(2\eta + 5\eta^{2} + 2\eta^{3} )\). Thus, when \(0 < G < \frac{{4(2\eta + 5\eta^{2} + 2\eta^{3} )}}{{A_{11} }}\), we have \(p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PNC} < P^{M}\); when \(\frac{{4(2\eta + 5\eta^{2} + 2\eta^{3} )}}{{A_{11} }} < G < \frac{4}{A}\), we have \(p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PNC} > P^{M}\).
-
(5)
Comparison of \(p_{i}^{PBC}\) and \(p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PBC}\), \(p_{i}^{PNC}\) and \(p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PNC}\)
$$p_{i}^{PBC} - p_{i}^{PNC} = \frac{{A_{12} \alpha \gamma^{2} \left( {\frac{{\beta^{2} }}{\gamma } - \frac{{2\eta^{2} }}{{A_{6} }}} \right)}}{{\left[ {2\gamma ( 2+ \eta )- \beta^{2} ( 1+ \eta )} \right]\left( {2 + 4\eta + \eta^{2} } \right)^{{}} \left( {4\gamma - A\beta^{2} } \right)}}$$(34)
\(A_{12} = (6 + 17\eta + 13\eta^{2} + 2\eta^{3} ) - A(6 + 14\eta + 7\eta^{2} + \eta^{3} ) > 0\). Thus, when \(0 < G < \frac{{2\eta^{2} }}{{A_{12} }}\), we have \(p_{i}^{PBC} < p_{i}^{PNC}\); when \(\frac{{2\eta^{2} }}{{A_{12} }} < G < \frac{4}{A}\), we have \(p_{i}^{PBC} > p_{i}^{PNC}\).
\(A_{13} = (12 + 46\eta + 59\eta^{2} + 29\eta^{3} + 4\eta^{4} ) - A(12 + 40\eta + 42\eta^{2} + 16\eta^{3} + 2\eta^{4} ) > 0\). Thus, when \(0 < G < \frac{{2\eta^{3} }}{{A_{13} }}\), we have \(p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PBC} < p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PNC}\); when \(\frac{{2\eta^{3} }}{{A_{13} }} < G < \frac{4}{A}\), we have \(p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PBC} > p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PNC}\).
In summary, when \(0 < G < \hbox{min} G_{3}\), we obtain \(p_{i}^{PBC} = p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PBC} < p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PNC} < p_{i}^{PNC} < p_{{}}^{M}\); when \(\hbox{max} G_{3} < G < \frac{2(2 + \eta )}{1 + \eta }\), we obtain \(p_{{}}^{M} < p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PNC} < p_{i}^{PNC} < p_{i}^{PBC} = p_{j ,j \ne i}^{PBC}\).
Proof of Proposition 5
-
(1)
Comparison of \(\varPi_{S} (C)\) and \(\varPi_{S} (M)\)
Under the PBC mode, we have
Under the PNC mode, we have
Further, we obtain
Thus, \(\varPi_{S} (PBC) > \varPi_{S} (PNC)\).
-
(2)
Comparison of \(\varPi_{R} (M)\), \(\varPi_{{R_{i} }} (C)\) and \(\varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (C)\)
Under the PBC mode, we have
Let \(F(G) = 4\eta^{2} + G^{2} (\eta + \eta^{2} ) - G(\eta + \eta^{2} ) = 0\), we obtain \(G_{{}}^{*} = 2 \pm \frac{2}{{\sqrt {1 + \eta } }}\), and \(2 + \frac{2}{{\sqrt {1 + \eta } }} > \frac{2(2 + \eta )}{1 + \eta }\).
Thus, when \(0 < G < 2 - \frac{2}{{\sqrt {1 + \eta } }}\), we have \(\varPi_{R} (M) > \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC) = \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PBC)\); when \(2 - \frac{2}{{\sqrt {1 + \eta } }} < G < \frac{2(2 + \eta )}{1 + \eta }\), we have \(\varPi_{R} (M) < \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC) = \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PBC)\).
Under the PNC mode, we have
Let \(F(G) = aG^{2} + bG + c = 0\), we obtain \(G_{{}}^{*} = \frac{{ - b \pm \sqrt {b^{2} - 4ac} }}{2a}\), and \(\frac{{ - b + \sqrt {b^{2} - 4ac} }}{2a} > \frac{4}{A}\); \(a = 2A^{2} (1 + \eta )(2 + 4\eta + \eta^{2} )^{2} - B(2 + 3\eta )\), \(b = - 8[2A(1 + \eta )(2 + 4\eta + \eta^{2} )^{2} - B(2 + 3\eta )]\), \(c = 16[2(1 + \eta )(2 + 4\eta + \eta^{2} )^{2} - B(2 + 3\eta )]\). Thus, when \(0 < G < \frac{{ - b - \sqrt {b^{2} - 4ac} }}{2a}\), we have \(\varPi_{R} (M) > \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PNC)\); when \(\frac{{ - b - \sqrt {b^{2} - 4ac} }}{2a} < G < \frac{4}{A}\), we have \(\varPi_{R} (M) < \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PNC)\). In the same way, when \(0 < G < \frac{{ - b_{1} - \sqrt {b_{1}^{2} - 4a_{1} c_{1} } }}{{2a_{1} }}\), we have \(\varPi_{R} (M) > \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PNC)\); when \(\frac{{ - b_{1} - \sqrt {b_{1}^{2} - 4a_{1} c_{1} } }}{{2a_{1} }} < G < \frac{4}{A}\), we have \(\varPi_{R} (M) < \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PNC)\). Wherein, \(a_{1}\), \(b_{1}\) and \(c_{1}\) can be obtained by \(\varPi_{R} (M) - \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PNC) = 0\). Therefore, when \(0 < G < \frac{{ - b_{1} - \sqrt {b_{1}^{2} - 4a_{1} c_{1} } }}{{2a_{1} }}\), we have \(\varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PNC) < \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC) = \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PBC) < \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PNC)\), when \(\frac{{ - b_{1} - \sqrt {b_{1}^{2} - 4a_{1} c_{1} } }}{{2a_{1} }} < G < \frac{4}{A}\), we have \(\varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PNC) < \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PNC) < \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC) = \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PBC)\).
In summary, when \(0 < G < \hbox{min} G_{4}\), \(\varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PNC) < \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC) = \varPi_{{R_{j,j \ne i} }} (PBC) < \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PNC) < \varPi_{R} (M)\); when \(\hbox{max} G_{4} < G < \frac{2(2 + \eta )}{1 + \eta }\), we have \(\varPi_{R} (M) < \varPi_{{R_{j ,j \ne i} }} (PNC) < \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PNC) < \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC) = \varPi_{{R_{j ,j \ne i} }} (PBC)\).
\(\square\)
Proof of Proposition 6
In the case of effective implementation of the EPBC mode, when \(\kappa_{i} > \kappa_{j,j \ne i}\), we have
When \(\kappa_{i} < \kappa_{j,j \ne i}\), we have
Finally, combined with the constraint of effective implementation of the EPBC mode, we obtain \(0 < \kappa_{i} + \kappa_{j ,j \ne i} < \sqrt {8\gamma (2 + \eta )/(1 + \eta )} - 2\beta\).
Let \(\kappa = \kappa_{i} + \kappa_{j ,j \ne i} = \sqrt {8\gamma (2 + \eta )/(1 + \eta )} - 2\beta\), we have \(\frac{d\kappa }{d\beta } = - 2 < 0\), That is, \(\kappa\) decreases with \(\beta\). Therefore, the total technology marketing effect (\(\kappa = \kappa_{i} + \kappa_{j ,j \ne i}\)) and the technology spillover effect \(\beta\) form a complementary relationship; when \(\kappa_{i}\) is constant, we can verify that the technology marketing effect \(\kappa_{j ,j \ne i}\) and the technology spillover effect \(\beta\) form a complementary relationship; when \(\kappa_{j ,j \ne i}\) is unchanged, we can also verify that the technology marketing effect \(\kappa_{i}\) and the technology spillover effect \(\beta\) form a complementary relationship. \(\square\)
Proof of Proposition 7
-
(1)
After comparing PBC mode and EPBC mode, we have
$$\varPi_{S} (EPBC) - \varPi_{S} (PBC) = w^{EPBC} (Q_{i}^{EPBC} + Q_{j ,j \ne i}^{EPBC} )- \gamma (\theta^{EPBC} )^{2} - \frac{{\alpha^{2} (1 + \eta )}}{2(2 + \eta ) - G(1 + \eta )} > 0$$(41)
Therefore, the optimal strategic mode of technology service provider is EPBC mode.
-
(2)
After comparing PBC mode and EPBC mode, we have
$$\varPi_{{R_{i} }} (EPBC) - \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC) = (p_{i}^{EPBC} - w^{EPBC} )Q_{i}^{EPBC} - F - \frac{{\alpha^{2} (1 + \eta )}}{{\left[ {2(2 + \eta ) - G(1 + \eta )} \right]^{2} }}$$(42)
Let \(\varPi_{{R_{i} }} (EPBC) - \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC) = 0\), we obtain
When \(\kappa_{i} > \kappa_{j,j \ne i}\), two thresholds of \(F\) are
Wherein, \(\kappa_{i}^{ *} + \kappa_{j,j \ne i}^{ *} = \arg \hbox{max} \{ 8\gamma (2 + \eta ) - (1 + \eta )(2\beta + \kappa_{i} + \kappa_{j ,j \ne i} )^{2} \}\), thus \(F_{1} < F_{2}\).
If \(F > F_{2}\), we have \(\varPi_{{R_{i} }} (EPBC) - \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC) < 0\), \(\varPi_{{R_{j} }} (EPBC) - \varPi_{{R_{j} }} (PBC) < 0\), that is, the optimal strategic mode of retailer \(R_{i}\) and \(R_{j,j \ne i}\) is PBC; if \(F_{1} < F < F_{2}\), we have \(\varPi_{{R_{i} }} (EPBC)\left| {_{{\kappa_{i}^{ *} + \kappa_{j,j \ne i}^{ *} }} } \right. - \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC) > 0\), \(\varPi_{{R_{j} }} (EPBC) - \varPi_{{R_{j} }} (PBC) < 0\), that is, the optimal strategic mode of retailer \(R_{i}\) is EPBC mode, while the optimal strategic mode of retailer \(R_{j,j \ne i}\) is PBC mode; if \(F < F_{1}\), we have \(\varPi_{{R_{i} }} (EPBC) - \varPi_{{R_{i} }} (PBC) > 0\), \(\varPi_{{R_{j} }} (EPBC) - \varPi_{{R_{j} }} (PBC) > 0\), that is, the optimal strategic mode of retailer \(R_{i}\) and \(R_{j,j \ne i}\) is EPBC mode. When \(\kappa_{i} < \kappa_{j,j \ne i}\), the same conclusion can be obtained according to the above analysis. Therefore, there exists two thresholds \(F^{*} > 0\) and \(F^{**} ( \ge F^{*} )\) such that: if \(F < F^{*}\), EPBC mode is the optimal strategic choice of two retailers; if \(F^{*} < F < F^{**}\), the strategic mode choice between retailer \(R_{i}\) and \(R_{j,j \ne i}\) aren’t consistent (that is, retailer \(R_{j,j \ne i}\) with smaller technology marketing effect will choose PBC mode, while retailer \(R_{i}\) with greater technology marketing effect will choose EPBC mode); if \(F > F^{**}\), PBC mode is the optimal strategic choice of two retailers.
\(\square\)
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Hu, F., Zhou, Z. Monopoly or competition: strategic analysis of a retailing technology service provision. Electron Commer Res 22, 1651–1689 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-020-09426-z
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10660-020-09426-z