Abstract
The interaction between fiscal and monetary policy is analyzed by means of a game theory approach. The coordination between these two policies is essential, since decisions taken by one institution may have disastrous effects on the other one, resulting in welfare loss for the society. We derived optimal monetary and fiscal policies in context of three coordination schemes: when each institution independently minimizes its welfare loss as a Nash equilibrium of a normal form game; when an institution moves first and the other follows, in a mechanism known as the Stackelberg solution; and, when institutions behave cooperatively, seeking common goals. In the Brazilian case, a numerical exercise shows that the smallest welfare loss is obtained under a Stackelberg solution which has the monetary policy as leader and the fiscal policy as follower. Under the optimal policy, there is evidence of a strong distaste for inflation by the Brazilian society.







Similar content being viewed by others
Notes
Macroeconomic policy characterized by absence of commitment.
This is a mechanism of decision-making in the European Central Bank (ECB).
The hat notation is used to denote deviations from the steady state in logarithm form.
Equation (3) might bring on a multiplier effect into the other equations, which is neglected under the current solution.
Note that the dating of the expectations operator captures the idea of the policy maker choosing a rule ex-ante which will be followed in the future. As we have a solution under commitment, the Lagrangian is solved for expectations at time zero, which characterizes the time when the rule was defined, thereafter followed without deviations. Thus, we removed the expectations operator on both inflation and output gap at t+1.
This solution coincides with that proposed by Woodford (2003).
The Real Plan was edited in June 1994.
See Woodford (2003) for details.
In order to simplify the notation, we will not distinguish between social loss and expected social loss.
References
Backus, D., & Driffill, D. (1985). Rational expectations and policy credibility following a change in regime. Review of Economic Studies, 52, 211–221.
Barcelos Neto, P. C. F., & Portugal, M. S. (2009). The natural rate of interest in Brazil between 1999 and 2005. Revista Brasileira de Economia, 63(2), 103–118.
Boucekkine, R. (1995). An alternative methodology for solving nonlinear forward-looking variables. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 19, 711–734.
Buiter, W. H. (1982). Predetermined and non-predetermined variables in rational expectations models. Economics Letters, 10, 49–54.
Bénassy, J. P. (2007). Money, interest and policy: dynamic general equilibrium in a non-Ricardian world. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Calvo, G. A. (1983). Staggered prices in a utility maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12, 383–398.
Cavallari, M. C. L. (2003). A coordenação das políticas fiscal e monetária ótimas. In Proceedings of the 31st Brazilian economics meeting.
Collard, F., & Juillard, M. (2001a). Accuracy of stochastic perturbation methods: the case of asset pricing models. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 25, 979–999.
Collard, F., & Juillard, M. (2001b). A higher-order Taylor expansion approach to simulation of stochastic forward-looking models with and application to a non-linear Phillips curve. Computational Economics, 17, 127–139.
Damjanovic, T., Damjanovic, V., & Nolan, C. (2005). Optimal monetary policy rules from a timeless perspective. Centre for Dynamic Macroeconomic analysis working papers series.
Dixit, A. (2001). Games of monetary and fiscal interactions in the EMU. European Economic Review, 45, 589–613.
Dixit, A., & Lambertini, L. (2000). Fiscal discretion destroys monetary commitment. Available at SSRN http://ssrn.com/abstract=232654.
Engwerda, J. C. (1998). On the open-loop Nash equilibrium in LQ-games. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 22, 1487–1506.
Engwerda, J. C., van Aarle, B., & Plasmans, J. (1999). The (in)finite horizon open-loop Nash LQ-game: an application to the EMU. Annals of Operations Research, 88, 251–273.
Engwerda, J. C., van Aarle, B., & Plasmans, J. (2002). Cooperative and non-cooperative fiscal stabilization policies in the EMU. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 26, 451–481.
Favero, C. A. (2004). Comments on fiscal and monetary policy interactions: empirical evidence on optimal policy using a structural new-Keynesian model. Journal of Macroeconomics, 26, 281–285.
Fialho, M. L., & Portugal, M. S. (2005). Monetary and fiscal policy interactions in Brazil: an application to the fiscal theory of the price level. Estudos Econômicos, 35(4), 657–685.
Gadelha, S. R. B., & Divino, J. A. (2008). Dominância fiscal ou dominância monetária no Brasil? uma análise de causalidade. Brazilian Journal of Applied Economics, 12(4), 659–675.
Giannoni, M. P., & Woodford, M. (2002a). NBER working paper series: Vol. 9419. Optimal interest-rate rules: I. General theory.
Giannoni, M. P., & Woodford, M. (2002b). NBER working paper series: Vol. 9420. Optimal interest-rate rules: II. Applications.
Gouvea, S. (2007). Central Bank of Brazil working papers: Vol. 143. Price rigidity in Brazil: evidence from CPI micro data. Available at http://ideas.repec.org/p/bcb/wpaper/143.html.
Juillard, M. (1996). CEPREMAP working papers (Couverture Orange): Vol. 9602. Dynare: a program for the resolution and simulation of dynamic models with forward variables through the use of relaxation algorithm. Available at http://ideas.repec.org/p/cpm/cepmap/9602.html.
Juillard, M., & Pelgrin, F. (2007). Computing optimal policy in a timeless-perspective: an application to a small-open economy. Working papers, 07–32, Bank of Canada.
Kirsanova, T., Stehn, S. J., & Vines, D. (2005). The interactions between fiscal policy and monetary policy. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 21(4), 532–564.
Klein, P. (2000). Using the generalized Schur form to solve a multivariate linear rational expectations model. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 24(10), 1405–1423.
Laffargue, J. (1990). Résolution d’un modèle macroéconomique avec anticipations rationnelles. Annales d’Économie et de Statistique, 17, 97–119.
Lambertini, L., & Rovelli, R. (2003). Monetary and fiscal policy coordination and macroeconomic stabilization. A theoretical analysis. Available at SSRN http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.380322.
Muscatelli, V., Tirelli, P., & Trecroci, C. (2004). Fiscal and monetary policy interactions: empirical evidence and optimal policy using a structural new-Keynesian model. Journal of Macroeconomics, 26, 257–280.
Nordhaus, W. (1994). Policy games: coordination and independence in monetary and fiscal polices. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 139–216.
Nunes, A. F. N., & Portugal, M. S. (2009). Active and passive fiscal and monetary policies: an analysis for Brazil after the inflation targeting regime. In Proceedings of the 37th Brazilian economics meeting.
Pires, M. C. C. (2008). Interação entre política monetária e fiscal no Brasil em modelos robustos a pequenas amostras. Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Economics, Brasília, University of Brasília.
Tabellini, G. (1985). Rational expectations and policy credibility following a change in regime. Giornali degli Economisti e Annali di Economia, 44, 389–425.
Tanner, E., & Ramos, A. M. (2002). Fiscal sustainability and monetary versus fiscal dominance: evidence from Brazil 1991–2000. IMF Working Paper, 02/5.
Taylor, J. (1993). Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39, 195–214.
Van Aarle, B., Engwerda, J., & Plasmans, J. (2002). Monetary and fiscal policy interactions in the EMU: a dynamic game approach. Annals of Operations Research, 109, 229–264.
Walsh, C. E. (2003). Monetary theory and policy. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Woodford, M. (1999). NBER Working paper series: Vol. 7261. Optimal monetary policy inertia.
Woodford, M. (2003). Interest and prices: foundations of a theory of monetary policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Acknowledgements
J.A. Divino and H. Saulo acknowledge CNPq for the financial support. L.C. Rêgo acknowledges financial support from FACEPE under grants APQ-0150-1.02/06 and APQ-0219-3.08/08, and from MCT/CNPq under grants 475634/2007-1 and 306358/2010-7.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendices
Appendix A
In this appendix we describe the general linear-quadratic policy approach introduced by Giannoni and Woodford (2002a) with applications by Giannoni and Woodford (2002a), to derive an optimal monetary policy rule. Note that this approach can easily be extended to the fiscal optimization problems discussed in this paper.
Woodford (2003, pp. 23–24) argues that standard dynamic programming methods are valid only for optimization problems that evolve in response to the current action of the controller. Hence, they do not apply to problems of monetary stabilization policy since the central bank’s actions depend on both the sequence of instrument settings in the present time and the private-sector’s expectations regarding future policies. A direct implementation of the maximum principle is not indicated, since we have discrete-time problems with conditional expectations on some variables which affect the solution under commitment.
1.1 A.1 General linear-quadratic policy problem
Giannoni and Woodford (2002a) deal with policy problems in which the constraints for the various state variables can be represented by a system of linear (or log-linear) equations, and in which a quadratic function of these variables can be used to represent the policymaker’s objectives. In general, the optimal policy rules considered by the authors take the form
where i t is the policy instrument, \(\bar{z}_{t}\) and \(\bar{Z}_{t}\) are the vectors of nonpredetermined and predetermined endogenous variables (e.g., the output gap forecast E t x t+k may be an element of \(\bar{z}_{t}\)), \(\bar{s}_{t}\) is a vector of exogenous state variables, and ϕ i , ϕ z , ϕ Z , and ϕ s , are vectors of coefficients and \(\bar{\phi}\) is a constant. As pointed out by Buiter (1982), a variable is nonpredetermined if and only if its current value is a function of current anticipations of future values of endogenous and/or exogenous variables. It is predetermined if its current value depends only on past values of endogenous and/or exogenous variables.
The discounted quadratic loss function is assumed to have the form
where t 0 stands for the initial date at which a policy rule is adopted, 0<β<1 denotes the discount factor, and L t specifies the period loss, that is,
where τ t is a vector of target variables, τ ∗ is its corresponding vector of target values, and W is a symmetric, positive-definite matrix. The target variables are assumed to be linear functions
where y t ≡[Z t z t i t ]⊤, Z t is a subset of the predetermined variables \(\bar{Z}_{t}\), z t is a subset of the vector of nonpredetermined endogenous variables \(\bar{z}_{t}\), and T is a matrix of coefficients. It is assumed that Z t encompasses all of the predetermined endogenous variables that constrain the possible equilibrium evolution of the variables Z T and z T for T≥t. Also, s t , i.e. the subset of exogenous states, encompasses all of the exogenous states which possess information on the possible future evolution of the variables Z T and z T for T≥t.
The endogenous variables z t and Z t take the form
where each matrix has n=n z +n Z rows, n z and n Z denotes the number of nonpredetermined and predetermined endogenous variables, respectively. Note that we may partition the matrices as
where the upper and lower blocks have n Z and n z rows, respectively. The zero restrictions in the upper blocks refer to the fact that the first n Z equations define the elements of Z t as elements of z t−j for some j≥1. It is assumed that A 22 is non-singular in order to let the last n z equations be solved for z t as a function of Z t , s t , i t , and E t z t+1. In addition, B 2 is not zero in all elements, resulting in an instrument with some effect.
Definition
(Giannoni and Woodford 2002a)
A policy rule that determines a unique non-explosive rational expectations equilibrium is optimal from a timeless perspective if the equilibrium determined by the rule is such that (a) the nonpredetermined endogenous variables z t can be expressed as a time-invariant function of a vector of predetermined variables \(\bar{Z}_{t}\) and a vector of exogenous variables \(\bar{s}_{t}\); that is, a relation of the form \(z_{t}=f_{0}+f_{Z}\bar{Z}_{t}+f_{s}\bar {s}_{t}\), applies for all dates t≥t 0; and (b) the equilibrium evolution of the endogenous variables {y t } for all dates t≥t 0 minimizes (32) among the set of all bounded processes, subject to the constraints implied by the economy’s initial state \(Z_{t_{0}}\), the requirements for rational expectations equilibrium (i.e., the structural equations (35)), and a set of additional constraints of the form
on the initial behavior of the nonpredetermined endogenous variables.
According to Woodford (1999), the Lagrangian for the minimization problem can be written as
where \(\tilde{A}\equiv[ A \ B ]\) and \(\tilde{I}\equiv[ \hat {I} \ 0 ]\). Note that L(y t ) denotes the period loss L t expressed as a quadratic function of y t and φ t+1 denotes the vector of Lagrange multipliers related to the constraints (35). Applying the law of iterated expectations, the conditional expectation can be eliminated from the term E t z t+1 in these constraints. Set
and insert the term
into (37), where \(\xi_{t_{0}}'Z_{t_{0}}\) represents the constraints imposed by the given initial values \(Z_{t_{0}}\), and \(\varXi_{t_{0}-1}'\tilde {E}z_{t_{0}}\) represents the constraints (36). Finally, differentiating the Lagrangian (37) with respect to the endogenous variables y t , we yield the first-order conditions
for each t≥t 0. Solving (39) under some assumptions (Giannoni and Woodford 2002a), it is possible to obtain a policy rule of the form expressed in (31).
Appendix B
This appendix explains the solution method used to derive the optimal nominal interest rate rule given by (7). Note that a similar procedure can be used to derive the other optimal rules.
The monetary authority minimizes the constrained loss function given by:
where the constraints include Eqs. (1) and (2), and Λ 1,t and Λ 2,t are the Lagrange multipliers.
In order to write the first-order conditions, we need to differentiate this equation with respect to the instrument \((\hat{i}_{t}-i^{*})\) and the state variables π t and \(\hat{x}_{t}\). Before moving forward we need to consider how to deal with the expectation terms within the constraint. Since this is a policy under commitment, the dating of the expectations operator captures the idea of the policymaker choosing an ex-ante rule which will be followed in the future. Hence, the expectations operator on inflation and the output gap at t+1 are removed. For example, if the inflation rate which the policymaker sets influences both actual and expected inflation, then he may directly optimize over the two. The first-order conditions are:



Isolating Λ 1,t in (43) and inserting into (42), we obtain
where \(\varLambda_{1,t}=-\frac{\gamma_{i}}{\sigma}(\hat{i}_{t}-i^{*})\) and \(\varLambda_{1,t-1}=-\frac{\gamma_{i}}{\sigma}(\hat{i}_{t-1}-i^{*})\). Repeating the procedure for Λ 2,t , we can eliminate all the Lagrange multipliers in (41). Then, isolating \(\hat{i}_{t}\) we have
where \(\varGamma_{0}=\frac{\sigma\kappa}{\beta}\), \(\varGamma_{i,1}= (\frac {\sigma\kappa}{\beta}+\frac{1}{\beta}+1 )\), \(\varGamma_{i,2}=\frac {1}{\beta}\), \(\varGamma_{\pi,0}=\frac{\gamma_{\pi}\sigma\kappa}{\gamma_{i}}\), \(\varGamma _{x,0}=\frac{\gamma_{x}\sigma}{\gamma_{i}}\), and \(\varGamma_{x,1}=\frac{\gamma _{x}\sigma}{\gamma_{i}}\).
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Saulo, H., Rêgo, L.C. & Divino, J.A. Fiscal and monetary policy interactions: a game theory approach. Ann Oper Res 206, 341–366 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-013-1379-3
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-013-1379-3