Abstract
This paper considers competition of duopolistic retailers, who sell substitutable products supplied by a single manufacturer offering a vertical cooperative advertising program. The price-dependent component of the demand function is derived from the consumers’ utility function in order to avoid logically inconsistent results. Additionally, each supply chain member can increase the costumers’ demand by advertising. By means of game theory, we get the following results: (a) Retailer competition harms all players, but is beneficial to the consumers. (b) Stronger competition is followed by less advertising. (c) Channel-leadership is not always advantageous to the manufacturer, and—likewise—retailers can also be better off when accepting followership. However, as our analysis shows, the increased complexity of the model under consideration reaches the limits of an analytical solution. Therefore, we give a brief outlook on non-nalytical solution methods for Nash and Stackelberg games, that could be used in future research, in the end of our paper.
Similar content being viewed by others
References
Ahmadi-Javid A, Hoseinpour P (2012) On a cooperative advertising model for a supply chain with one manufacturer and one retailer. Eur J Oper Res 219(2):458–466
Aust G, Buscher U (2012) Vertical cooperative advertising and pricing decisions in a manufacturer-retailer supply chain: a game-theoretic approach. Eur J Oper Res 223(2):473–482
Aust G, Buscher U (2013) Vertical cooperative advertising in a retailer duopoly. Dresdner Beiträge zur Betriebswirtschaftslehre (171/13), TU Dresden, Fakultät Wirtschaftswissenschaften
Bard JF (1998) Practical bilevel optimization: algorithms and applications, nonconvex optimization and its applications, vol 30. Kluwer Academic Publishers, New York
Bergen M, John G (1997) Understanding cooperative advertising participation rates in conventional channels. J Mark Res 34(3):357–369
Berger PD (1972) Vertical cooperative advertising ventures. J Mark Res 9(3):309–312
Bianco L, Caramia M, Giordani S (2009) A bilevel flow model for hazmat transportation network design. Transp Res Part C Emerg Technol 17(2):175–196
Choi SC (1991) Price competition in a channel structure with a common retailer. Mark Sci 10(4):271–296
Choi SC (1996) Price competition in a duopoly common retailer channel. J Retail 72(2):117–134
Chutani A, Sethi SP (2012) Cooperative advertising in a dynamic retail market oligopoly. Dyn Games Appl 2(4):347–375
Colson B, Marcotte P, Savard G (2007) An overview of bilevel optimization. Ann Oper Res 153(1):235–256
Dempe S (2002) Foundations of bilevel programming, nonconvex optimization and its applications, vol 61. Kluwer Academic Publishers, New York
Dutta S, Bergen M, John G, Rao A (1995) Variations in the contractual terms of cooperative advertising contracts: an empirical investigation. Mark Lett 6(1):15–22
Ghadimi S, Szidarovszky F, Farahani RZ, Khiabani AY (2013) Coordination of advertising in supply chain management with cooperating manufacturer and retailers. IMA J Manag Math 24(1):1–19
He X, Krishnamoorthy A, Prasad A, Sethi SP (2011) Retail competition and cooperative advertising. Oper Res Lett 39(1):11–16
He X, Krishnamoorthy A, Prasad A, Sethi SP (2012) Co-op advertising in dynamic retail oligopolies. Decis Sci 43(1):73–106
Huang Z, Li SX (2001) Co-op advertising models in manufacturer-retailer supply chains: a game theory approach. Eur J Oper Res 135(3):527–544
Ingene CA, Parry ME (2004) Mathematical models of distribution channels. Kluwer Academic Publishers, New York
Ingene CA, Parry ME (2007) Bilateral monopoly, identical distributors, and game-theoretic analyses of distribution channels. J Acad Mark Sci 35(4):586–602
Karray S, Zaccour G (2006) Could co-op advertising be a manufacturer’s counterstrategy to store brands? J Bus Res 59(9):1008–1015
Karray S, Zaccour G (2007) Effectiveness of coop advertising programs in competitive distribution channels. Int Game Theory Rev 9(2):151–167
Kim SY, Staelin R (1999) Manufacturer allowances and retailer pass-through rates in a competitive environment. Mark Sci 18(1):59–76
Nagler M (2006) An exploratory analysis of the determinants of cooperative advertising participation rates. Mark Lett 17:91–102
Naoum-Sawaya J, Elhedhli S (2011) Controlled predatory pricing in a multiperiod stackelberg game: an MPEC approach. J Glob Optim 50(2):345–362
Pedroso JP (1996) Numerical solution of nash and stackelberg equilibria: an evolutionary approach. In: Proceedings of the First Asia Conference on Simulated Evolution and Learning, Korea
Rajabioun R, Atashpaz-Gargari E, Lucas C (2008) Colonial competitive algorithm as a tool for nash equilibrium point achievement. In: Gervasi O, Murgante B, Laganà A, Taniar D, Mun Y, Gavrilova ML (eds) Computational science and its applications—ICCSA 2008, vol 5073. Lecture notes in computer science. Springer, Berlin, pp 680–695
Rajesh J, Gupta K, Kusumakar HS, Jayaraman VK, Kulkarni BD (2003) A tabu search based approach for solving a class of bilevel programming problems in chemical engineering. J Heuristics 9(4):307–319
Sadigh AN, Mozafari M, Karimi B (2012) Manufacturer-retailer supply chain coordination: a bi-level programming approach. Adv Eng Softw 45(1):144–152
Sefrioui M, Perlaux J (2000) Nash genetic algorithms: examples and applications. In: Proceedings of the 2000 congress on evolutionary Computation, vol 1, pp 509–516
SeyedEsfahani MM, Biazaran M, Gharakhani M (2011) A game theoretic approach to coordinate pricing and vertical co-op advertising in manufacturer-retailer supply chains. Eur J Oper Res 211(2):263–273
Sinha A, Malo P, Frantsev A, Deb K (2014) Finding optimal strategies in a multi-period multi-leader-follower stackelberg game using an evolutionary algorithm. Comput Oper Res 41:374–385
Somers TM, Gupta YP, Harriot SR (1990) Analysis of cooperative advertising expenditures: a transfer-function modeling approach. J Advert Res 30(5):35–49
Szmerekovsky JG, Zhang J (2009) Pricing and two-tier advertising with one manufacturer and one retailer. Eur J Oper Res 192(3):904–917
Talbi EG (ed) (2013) Metaheuristics for bi-level optimization, studies in computational intelligence, vol 482. Springer, Heidelberg
Wang SD, Zhou YW, Wang JP (2010) Coordinating ordering, pricing and advertising policies for a supply chain with random demand and two production modes. Int J Prod Econ 126(2):168–180
Wang SD, Zhou YW, Min J, Zhong YG (2011) Coordination of cooperative advertising models in a one-manufacturer two-retailer supply chain system. Comput Ind Eng 61(4):1053–1071
Wu CH, Chen CW, Hsieh CC (2012) Competitive pricing decisions in a two-echelon supply chain with horizontal and vertical competition. Int J Prod Econ 135(1):265–274
Xie J, Neyret A (2009) Co-op advertising and pricing models in manufacturer-retailer supply chains. Comput Ind Eng 56(4):1375–1385
Xie J, Wei JC (2009) Coordinating advertising and pricing in a manufacturer-retailer channel. Eur J Oper Res 197(2):785–791
Yan R (2010) Cooperative advertising, pricing strategy and firm performance in the e-marketing age. J Acad Mark Sci 38:510–519
Yang SL, Zhou YW (2006) Two-echelon supply chain models: considering duopolistic retailers’ different competitive behaviors. Int J Prod Econ 103(1):104–116
Yu Y, Huang GQ (2010) Nash game model for optimizing market strategies, configuration of platform products in a vendor managed inventory (VMI) supply chain for a product family. Eur J Oper Res 206(2):361–373
Yue J, Austin J, Wang MC, Huang Z (2006) Coordination of cooperative advertising in a two-level supply chain when manufacturer offers discount. Eur J Oper Res 168(1):65–85
Zhang J, Xie J (2012) A game theoretical study of cooperative advertising with multiple retailers in a distribution channel. J Syst Sci Syst Eng 21(1):37–55
Zhang R, Liu B, Wang W (2012) Pricing decisions in a dual channels system with different power structures. Econ Model 29(2):523–533
Zhao J, Tang W, Zhao R, Wei J (2012) Pricing decisions for substitutable products with a common retailer in fuzzy environments. Eur J Oper Res 216(2):409–419
Acknowledgments
The authors are very grateful to the editor and to the two anonymous reviewers for their valuable comments which helped improving the quality of our paper.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Corresponding author
Appendix
Appendix
Proof
(Proposition 1) We start with the manufacturer’s decision problem stated in Eq. (11) and set the first order partial derivatives \(\partial \pi _{\mathrm {m}}/ \partial w\) and \(\partial \pi _{\mathrm {m}}/ \partial A\) to zero:
Please note that participation rate \(t\) equals zero due to its solely negative influence on the manufacturer’s profit function. From Eqs. (17) and (18), we derive:
Likewise, we calculate the first order partial derivatives of the retailers’ decision problems (see Eq. (12)), \(\partial \pi _{\mathrm {r}i}/\partial m_i\) and \(\partial \pi _{\mathrm {r}i}/ \partial a_i\), and set them to zero:
From these equations, we derive:
With \(t=0\), we can now solve the system of equations described by Eqs. (17)–(20), which leads us to the expressions stated in Proposition 1. This completes proof of Proposition 1.
Proof
(Proposition 2) The retailers’ decision problems in a Manufacturer Stackelberg—Horizontal Nash game are identical to Eq. (12) and have the solutions stated in Eqs. (23) and (24). These expressions can be rearranged to
Constituting the constraints of the manufacturer’s decision problem [see Eq. (15)], these response functions have to be inserted into the manufacturer’s profit function. In order to reduce the complexness of this problem, we set \(\varLambda _1 = \varLambda _2 = \varLambda \), which leads to \(\alpha _1 = \alpha _2 = \alpha \). Hence, we can rewrite Eqs. (25) and (26) as follows:
Inserting these equations into the profit function stated in Eq. (15), we get:
By setting the first order partial derivative \(\partial \pi _{\mathrm {m}}/ \partial A\) to zero,
we can determine the optimal global advertising expenditures as a function of \(w\):
Setting the first order partial derivative \(\partial \pi _{\mathrm {m}}/ \partial t\) to zero,
leads us to
As described in Sect. 2, the participation rate is only defined within \(0\le t <1\). However, Eq. (33) can take negative values for \(w<\alpha / (9\beta -5\epsilon )\). In this case, we have to set \(t=0\) to avoid mathematical inconsistencies.
The first order partial derivative \(\partial \pi _{\mathrm {m}}/ \partial w\) is
and is also set to zero. This equation can be simplified by inserting Eq. (31):
Due to the non-negativity restriction of \(t\), we now have to conduct a case-by-case analysis. For \(w\ge \alpha / (9\beta -5\epsilon )\), we insert Eq. (33) into Eq. (35):
The solution of this expression are given as \(\tilde{w}_1\) and \(\tilde{w}_2\) in Step 1 of the solution procedure stated in Proposition 2. For \(w<\alpha / (9\beta -5\epsilon )\), we insert \(t=0\) into Eq. (35):
The solution of this expression are given as \(\tilde{w}_3\) and \(\tilde{w}_4\) in Step 1 of the solution procedure stated in Proposition 2. This completes proof of Proposition 2.
Proof
(Proposition 3) As defined in Sect. 2, \(\alpha _i\) is a function of \(\varLambda _i\) with
Due to the positive first order derivative \(\partial \alpha _i/\partial \varLambda _i\) and the chain rule \(\mathrm {d} f(h(x)) / \mathrm {d} x = \mathrm {d} f(h(x)) / \mathrm {d} h(x) \cdot \mathrm {d} h(x) / \mathrm {d} x\), the first order derivative with respect to \(\alpha _i\) has the same prefix as the first order derivation with respect to \(\varLambda _i\). Hence, one can easily make the conclusions given in Part (i) and Part (ii) of Proposition 3 with the following first order derivatives:
Due to the complexity of the resulting first order derivatives \(\partial \pi _{\mathrm {r}i}/ \partial \alpha _i\) and \(\partial \pi _{\mathrm {r}i}/ \partial \alpha _{3-i}\), we are not able to proof Part (iii) of Proposition 3 analytically. Instead of that, we computed a numerical study with 3,000,000 randomly generated sets of parameters within the range \(10\le \alpha _i\le 30\) and \(0.1\le \beta ,\epsilon ,k_{\mathrm {m}},k_{\mathrm {r}}\le 10\) and could thereby show numerically that \(\partial \pi _{\mathrm {r}i}/ \partial \alpha _i >0\) and \(\partial \pi _{\mathrm {r}i}/ \partial \alpha _{3-i} >0\) holds for each considered combination of parameters—except 18 cases with \(\beta \approx 0.1\) and \(\epsilon >5\), which violate the condition \(\beta >\epsilon \) resulting from \(B>\varTheta \) given in Sect. 2, though.
Hence, we are confident that the given inequalities hold for feasible parameter combinations. This completes proof of Proposition 3.
Rights and permissions
About this article
Cite this article
Aust, G., Buscher, U. Game theoretic analysis of pricing and vertical cooperative advertising of a retailer-duopoly with a common manufacturer. Cent Eur J Oper Res 24, 127–147 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10100-014-0338-7
Published:
Issue Date:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10100-014-0338-7