{"status":"ok","message-type":"work","message-version":"1.0.0","message":{"indexed":{"date-parts":[[2024,7,9]],"date-time":"2024-07-09T00:57:53Z","timestamp":1720486673363},"reference-count":40,"publisher":"Elsevier BV","license":[{"start":{"date-parts":[[2024,3,1]],"date-time":"2024-03-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1709251200000},"content-version":"tdm","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/www.elsevier.com\/tdm\/userlicense\/1.0\/"},{"start":{"date-parts":[[2024,3,1]],"date-time":"2024-03-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1709251200000},"content-version":"stm-asf","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.15223\/policy-017"},{"start":{"date-parts":[[2024,3,1]],"date-time":"2024-03-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1709251200000},"content-version":"stm-asf","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.15223\/policy-037"},{"start":{"date-parts":[[2024,3,1]],"date-time":"2024-03-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1709251200000},"content-version":"stm-asf","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.15223\/policy-012"},{"start":{"date-parts":[[2024,3,1]],"date-time":"2024-03-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1709251200000},"content-version":"stm-asf","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.15223\/policy-029"},{"start":{"date-parts":[[2024,3,1]],"date-time":"2024-03-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1709251200000},"content-version":"stm-asf","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.15223\/policy-004"}],"content-domain":{"domain":["elsevier.com","sciencedirect.com"],"crossmark-restriction":true},"short-container-title":["Mathematical Social Sciences"],"published-print":{"date-parts":[[2024,3]]},"DOI":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001","type":"journal-article","created":{"date-parts":[[2024,2,3]],"date-time":"2024-02-03T16:07:29Z","timestamp":1706976449000},"page":"100-109","update-policy":"http:\/\/dx.doi.org\/10.1016\/elsevier_cm_policy","source":"Crossref","is-referenced-by-count":0,"special_numbering":"C","title":["Network externalities in a vertically differentiated luxury goods market"],"prefix":"10.1016","volume":"128","author":[{"ORCID":"http:\/\/orcid.org\/0000-0002-1269-4260","authenticated-orcid":false,"given":"Di","family":"Wu","sequence":"first","affiliation":[]},{"ORCID":"http:\/\/orcid.org\/0000-0002-5848-4971","authenticated-orcid":false,"given":"Ji","family":"Sun","sequence":"additional","affiliation":[]},{"ORCID":"http:\/\/orcid.org\/0000-0003-2919-2651","authenticated-orcid":false,"given":"Leonard F.S.","family":"Wang","sequence":"additional","affiliation":[]},{"ORCID":"http:\/\/orcid.org\/0000-0002-0795-1744","authenticated-orcid":false,"given":"Huizhong","family":"Liu","sequence":"additional","affiliation":[]}],"member":"78","reference":[{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0001","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"1203","DOI":"10.1007\/s00199-019-01229-0","article-title":"Oligopoly with network effects: firm-specific versus single network","volume":"71","author":"Amir","year":"2021","journal-title":"Econ. Theory"},{"issue":"6","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib40","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"1229","DOI":"10.1111\/jpet.12673","article-title":"First-best health policy in vaccine markets with health and network externalities","volume":"25","author":"Amir","year":"2023","journal-title":"J. Public Econ. Theory"},{"issue":"6","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0002","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"2389","DOI":"10.1016\/j.jet.2011.10.006","article-title":"Network effects, market structure and industry performance","volume":"146","author":"Amir","year":"2011","journal-title":"J. Econ. Theory"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0003","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"653","DOI":"10.1007\/s00199-002-0265-z","article-title":"Effect of credible quality investment with Bertrand and Cournot competition","volume":"21","author":"Aoki","year":"2003","journal-title":"Econ. Theory"},{"issue":"1\u20132","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0004","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"267","DOI":"10.1016\/S0167-7187(99)00029-6","article-title":"Vertical product differentiation, network externalities, and compatibility decisions","volume":"19","author":"Baake","year":"2001","journal-title":"Int. J. Industr. Organ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0005","first-page":"349","article-title":"Veblen effects in a theory of conspicuous consumption","volume":"86","author":"Bagwell","year":"1996","journal-title":"American Econ. Rev."},{"issue":"5","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0006","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"605","DOI":"10.1016\/j.ijindorg.2009.02.001","article-title":"Local network externalities and market segmentation","volume":"27","author":"Banerji","year":"2009","journal-title":"Int. J. Industr. Organ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0007","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"86","DOI":"10.1016\/j.jebo.2016.01.011","article-title":"Price equilibrium and willingness to pay in a vertically differentiated mixed duopoly","volume":"125","author":"Benassi","year":"2016","journal-title":"J. Econ. Behav. Organ"},{"issue":"5","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0008","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"841","DOI":"10.1086\/261957","article-title":"A theory of conformity","volume":"102","author":"Bernheim","year":"1994","journal-title":"J. Polit. Econ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0009","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"1","DOI":"10.1007\/s10640-012-9576-0","article-title":"Environmental quality competition and taxation in the presence of green network effect among consumers","volume":"54","author":"Br\u00e9card","year":"2013","journal-title":"Environmen. Resour. Econ"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0010","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"141","DOI":"10.1007\/s00712-023-00834-x","article-title":"Strategic product compatibility in network industries","volume":"140","author":"Buccella","year":"2023","journal-title":"J. Econ."},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0011","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"259","DOI":"10.1515\/bejte-2020-0188","article-title":"Quality competition and market-share leadership in network industries","volume":"23","author":"Cheng","year":"2023","journal-title":"BE J. Theoret. Econ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0012","series-title":"Consumer Behaviour","author":"Chisnall","year":"1994"},{"issue":"473","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0013","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"642","DOI":"10.1111\/1468-0297.00654","article-title":"Status effects and negative utility growth","volume":"111","author":"Cooper","year":"2001","journal-title":"Econ. J."},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0014","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"55","DOI":"10.1016\/S0047-2727(97)00016-9","article-title":"Conspicuous consumption, snobbism and conformism","volume":"66","author":"Corneo","year":"1997","journal-title":"J. Public. Econ"},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0015","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"599","DOI":"10.2307\/2109809","article-title":"Competing compatibility standards and network externalities in the PC software market","volume":"77","author":"Gandal","year":"1995","journal-title":"Rev. Econ. Statistics"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0016","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"143","DOI":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2023.02.005","article-title":"Market-dependent preferences, positive and negative network effects and welfare","volume":"123","author":"Gaumont","year":"2023","journal-title":"Math Soc. Sci"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0017","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"27","DOI":"10.1016\/j.jpubeco.2016.08.004","article-title":"Network effects and environmental externalities: do clean technologies suffer from excess inertia?","volume":"143","author":"Greaker","year":"2016","journal-title":"J. Public. Econ"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0018","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"385","DOI":"10.1016\/S0047-2727(00)00115-8","article-title":"Price competition when consumer behavior is characterized by conformity or vanity","volume":"80","author":"Grilo","year":"2001","journal-title":"J. Public. Econ"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0019","series-title":"Social Limits to Growth","author":"Hirsch","year":"1976"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0020","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"487","DOI":"10.1016\/j.econlet.2012.06.045","article-title":"Strategic delegation under price competition and network effects","volume":"117","author":"Hoernig","year":"2012","journal-title":"Econ. Lett"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0021","first-page":"424","article-title":"Network externalities, competition, and compatibility","volume":"75","author":"Katz","year":"1985","journal-title":"American Econ. Rev."},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0022","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"822","DOI":"10.1086\/261409","article-title":"Technology adoption in the presence of network externalities","volume":"94","author":"Katz","year":"1986","journal-title":"J. Political Econ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0023","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"55","DOI":"10.1111\/j.1468-5876.2005.00300.x","article-title":"The existence of equilibrium in a differentiated duopoly with network externalities","volume":"56","author":"Lambertini","year":"2005","journal-title":"Japan. Econ. Rev."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0024","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"469","DOI":"10.1016\/j.jbusres.2019.01.017","article-title":"Exploring barriers to adoption of virtual reality through social media analytics and machine learning\u2013An assessment of technology, network, price and trialability","volume":"100","author":"Laurell","year":"2019","journal-title":"J. Bus. Res"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0025","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"183","DOI":"10.2307\/1882692","article-title":"Bandwagon, snob, and Veblen effects in the theory of consumers' demand","volume":"64","author":"Leibenstein","year":"1950","journal-title":"Quar. J. Econ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0026","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"37","DOI":"10.1111\/manc.12425","article-title":"Managerial delegation, network externalities and loan commitment","volume":"91","author":"Lian","year":"2023","journal-title":"Manch. School"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0027","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"27","DOI":"10.1111\/j.1467-8586.2007.00270.x","article-title":"A note on market coverage in vertical differentiation models with fixed costs","volume":"60","author":"Liao","year":"2008","journal-title":"Bull. Econ. Res"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0028","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"139","DOI":"10.1007\/s11151-017-9581-0","article-title":"Strategic choice of network externality and its impact on digital piracy","volume":"52","author":"Lu","year":"2018","journal-title":"Rev. Industr. Organ."},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0029","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"141","DOI":"10.1287\/mksc.7.2.141","article-title":"Product and price competition in a duopoly","volume":"7","author":"Moorthy","year":"1988","journal-title":"Mark. Sci."},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0030","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"113","DOI":"10.2307\/2950431","article-title":"Endogenous quality choice: price vs. quantity competition","volume":"41","author":"Motta","year":"1993","journal-title":"J. Industr. Econ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0031","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"51","DOI":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2019.11.006","article-title":"Network externalities and process R&D: a Cournot\u2013Bertrand comparison","volume":"103","author":"Naskar","year":"2020","journal-title":"Math Soc. Sci"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0032","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"94","DOI":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2015.02.007","article-title":"Cournot vs. Bertrand under relative performance delegation: implications of positive and negative network externalities","volume":"75","author":"Pal","year":"2015","journal-title":"Math Soc. Sci"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0033","series-title":"Bandwagon Effects in High-Technology Industries","author":"Rohlfs","year":"2003"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0034","series-title":"Information rules: A strategic Guide to the Network Economy","author":"Shapiro","year":"1999"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0035","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"159","DOI":"10.1016\/0148-2963(91)90050-8","article-title":"Why we buy what we buy: a theory of consumption values","volume":"22","author":"Sheth","year":"1991","journal-title":"J. Bus. Res"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0036","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"105","DOI":"10.1016\/j.jebo.2020.05.004","article-title":"Hotelling-Bertrand duopoly competition under firm-specific network effects","volume":"176","author":"Tolotti","year":"2020","journal-title":"J. Econ. Behav. Organ"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0037","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"149","DOI":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2021.06.001","article-title":"Vertical product differentiation, managerial delegation and social welfare in a vertically-related market","volume":"113","author":"Wang","year":"2021","journal-title":"Math. Soc. Sci"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0038","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"403","DOI":"10.1007\/s42973-020-00053-9","article-title":"Corporate social responsibility, vertical product differentiation, and privatization policy","volume":"73","author":"Wang","year":"2022","journal-title":"Japan. Econ. Rev."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001_bib0039","series-title":"The Theory of the Leisure class: An economic Study of Institutions","author":"Veblen","year":"1899"}],"container-title":["Mathematical Social Sciences"],"original-title":[],"language":"en","link":[{"URL":"https:\/\/api.elsevier.com\/content\/article\/PII:S0165489624000210?httpAccept=text\/xml","content-type":"text\/xml","content-version":"vor","intended-application":"text-mining"},{"URL":"https:\/\/api.elsevier.com\/content\/article\/PII:S0165489624000210?httpAccept=text\/plain","content-type":"text\/plain","content-version":"vor","intended-application":"text-mining"}],"deposited":{"date-parts":[[2024,3,6]],"date-time":"2024-03-06T18:57:13Z","timestamp":1709751433000},"score":1,"resource":{"primary":{"URL":"https:\/\/linkinghub.elsevier.com\/retrieve\/pii\/S0165489624000210"}},"subtitle":[],"short-title":[],"issued":{"date-parts":[[2024,3]]},"references-count":40,"alternative-id":["S0165489624000210"],"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001","relation":{},"ISSN":["0165-4896"],"issn-type":[{"value":"0165-4896","type":"print"}],"subject":[],"published":{"date-parts":[[2024,3]]},"assertion":[{"value":"Elsevier","name":"publisher","label":"This article is maintained by"},{"value":"Network externalities in a vertically differentiated luxury goods market","name":"articletitle","label":"Article Title"},{"value":"Mathematical Social Sciences","name":"journaltitle","label":"Journal Title"},{"value":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.1016\/j.mathsocsci.2024.02.001","name":"articlelink","label":"CrossRef DOI link to publisher maintained version"},{"value":"article","name":"content_type","label":"Content Type"},{"value":"\u00a9 2024 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.","name":"copyright","label":"Copyright"}]}}