{"status":"ok","message-type":"work","message-version":"1.0.0","message":{"indexed":{"date-parts":[[2024,9,15]],"date-time":"2024-09-15T17:20:53Z","timestamp":1726420853195},"reference-count":29,"publisher":"Elsevier BV","license":[{"start":{"date-parts":[[2023,3,1]],"date-time":"2023-03-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1677628800000},"content-version":"tdm","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/www.elsevier.com\/tdm\/userlicense\/1.0\/"},{"start":{"date-parts":[[2023,3,1]],"date-time":"2023-03-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1677628800000},"content-version":"stm-asf","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.15223\/policy-017"},{"start":{"date-parts":[[2023,3,1]],"date-time":"2023-03-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1677628800000},"content-version":"stm-asf","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.15223\/policy-037"},{"start":{"date-parts":[[2023,3,1]],"date-time":"2023-03-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1677628800000},"content-version":"stm-asf","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.15223\/policy-012"},{"start":{"date-parts":[[2023,3,1]],"date-time":"2023-03-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1677628800000},"content-version":"stm-asf","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.15223\/policy-029"},{"start":{"date-parts":[[2023,3,1]],"date-time":"2023-03-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1677628800000},"content-version":"stm-asf","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.15223\/policy-004"}],"content-domain":{"domain":["elsevier.com","sciencedirect.com"],"crossmark-restriction":true},"short-container-title":["Journal of Economic Theory"],"published-print":{"date-parts":[[2023,3]]},"DOI":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617","type":"journal-article","created":{"date-parts":[[2023,2,1]],"date-time":"2023-02-01T10:59:39Z","timestamp":1675249179000},"page":"105617","update-policy":"http:\/\/dx.doi.org\/10.1016\/elsevier_cm_policy","source":"Crossref","is-referenced-by-count":1,"special_numbering":"C","title":["Evolutionary foundation for heterogeneity in risk aversion"],"prefix":"10.1016","volume":"208","author":[{"ORCID":"http:\/\/orcid.org\/0000-0001-9712-5771","authenticated-orcid":false,"given":"Yuval","family":"Heller","sequence":"first","affiliation":[]},{"ORCID":"http:\/\/orcid.org\/0000-0002-4152-4113","authenticated-orcid":false,"given":"Ilan","family":"Nehama","sequence":"additional","affiliation":[]}],"member":"78","reference":[{"year":"1997","series-title":"Storage for Good Times and Bad: Of Rats and Men","author":"Bergstrom","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0010"},{"issue":"11","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0020","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"1","DOI":"10.1371\/journal.pone.0050310","article-title":"An evolutionary model of bounded rationality and intelligence","volume":"7","author":"Brennan","year":"2012","journal-title":"PLoS ONE"},{"issue":"6","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0030","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"1021","DOI":"10.1111\/j.1542-4774.2011.01046.x","article-title":"Relative risk aversion is constant: evidence from panel data","volume":"9","author":"Chiappori","year":"2011","journal-title":"J. Eur. Econ. Assoc."},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0040","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"119","DOI":"10.1016\/0022-5193(66)90188-3","article-title":"Optimizing reproduction in a randomly varying environment","volume":"12","author":"Cohen","year":"1966","journal-title":"J. Theor. Biol."},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0050","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"135","DOI":"10.1016\/0022-5193(82)90336-8","article-title":"Adaptive coin-flipping: a decision-theoretic examination of natural selection for random individual variation","volume":"94","author":"Cooper","year":"1982","journal-title":"J. Theor. Biol."},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0060","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"357","DOI":"10.1006\/jeth.2000.2719","article-title":"Decision making under uncertainty and the evolution of interdependent preferences","volume":"98","author":"Curry","year":"2001","journal-title":"J. Econ. Theory"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0070","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"1105","DOI":"10.1016\/j.jet.2012.01.003","article-title":"The exact law of large numbers for independent random matching","volume":"147","author":"Duffie","year":"2012","journal-title":"J. Econ. Theory"},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0080","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"517","DOI":"10.1016\/S0022-5193(05)80088-8","article-title":"Biological signals as handicaps","volume":"144","author":"Grafen","year":"1990","journal-title":"J. Theor. Biol."},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0090","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"473","DOI":"10.1016\/S0022-5193(05)80087-6","article-title":"Sexual selection unhandicapped by the Fisher process","volume":"144","author":"Grafen","year":"1990","journal-title":"J. Theor. Biol."},{"issue":"1421","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0100","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"799","DOI":"10.1098\/rspb.1999.0708","article-title":"Formal Darwinism, the individual-as-maximizing-agent analogy and bet-hedging","volume":"266","author":"Grafen","year":"1999","journal-title":"Proc. R. Soc. Lond. B, Biol. Sci."},{"year":"2015","series-title":"An Introduction to Genetic Analysis","author":"Griffiths","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0110"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0120","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"121","DOI":"10.1111\/j.1468-0262.2006.00651.x","article-title":"Random expected utility","volume":"74","author":"Gul","year":"2006","journal-title":"Econometrica"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0130","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"1","DOI":"10.2307\/2678130","article-title":"Demography of risk aversion","volume":"68","author":"Halek","year":"2001","journal-title":"J. Risk Insur."},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0140","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"134","DOI":"10.1257\/mic.6.1.134","article-title":"Overconfidence and diversification","volume":"6","author":"Heller","year":"2014","journal-title":"Am. Econ. J. Microecon."},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0150","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"403","DOI":"10.3982\/TE3949","article-title":"Evolution, heritable risk, and skewness loving","volume":"16","author":"Heller","year":"2021","journal-title":"Theor. Econ."},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0160","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"1056","DOI":"10.1073\/pnas.62.4.1056","article-title":"On population growth in a randomly varying environment","volume":"62","author":"Lewontin","year":"1969","journal-title":"Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0170","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","DOI":"10.1017\/S0140525X1900061X","article-title":"Resource-rational analysis: understanding human cognition as the optimal use of limited computational resources","volume":"43","author":"Lieder","year":"2020","journal-title":"Behav. Brain Sci."},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0180","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"185","DOI":"10.1007\/BF01237756","article-title":"Implicit frequency dependence and kin selection in fluctuating environments","volume":"9","author":"McNamara","year":"1995","journal-title":"Evol. Ecol."},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0190","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"937","DOI":"10.1257\/aer.99.3.937","article-title":"Evolution of time preferences and attitudes toward risk","volume":"99","author":"Netzer","year":"2009","journal-title":"Am. Econ. Rev."},{"year":"2021","series-title":"Endogenous Risk Attitudes","author":"Netzer","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0200"},{"issue":"12","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0210","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"2997","DOI":"10.1111\/j.1558-5646.2007.00237.x","article-title":"Absolute fitness, relative fitness, and utility","volume":"61","author":"Orr","year":"2007","journal-title":"Int. J. Org. Evol."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0220","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"410","DOI":"10.1016\/j.jet.2017.10.002","article-title":"On the biological foundation of risk preferences","volume":"172","author":"Robatto","year":"2017","journal-title":"J. Econ. Theory"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0230","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"397","DOI":"10.1006\/jeth.1996.0023","article-title":"A biological basis for expected and non-expected utility","volume":"68","author":"Robson","year":"1996","journal-title":"J. Econ. Theory"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0240","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"11","DOI":"10.1257\/jel.39.1.11","article-title":"The biological basis of economic behavior","volume":"39","author":"Robson","year":"2001","journal-title":"J. Econ. Lit."},{"issue":"26","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0250","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","DOI":"10.1073\/pnas.2015569118","article-title":"Evolved attitudes to risk and the demand for equity","volume":"118","author":"Robson","year":"2021","journal-title":"Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci."},{"issue":"5","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0260","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"1925","DOI":"10.1257\/aer.99.5.1925","article-title":"The evolution of time preference with aggregate uncertainty","volume":"99","author":"Robson","year":"2009","journal-title":"Am. Econ. Rev."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0270","series-title":"The Handbook of Social Economics, vol. 1","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"221","DOI":"10.1016\/B978-0-444-53187-2.00007-3","article-title":"The evolutionary foundations of preferences","author":"Robson","year":"2011"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0280","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"44","DOI":"10.1016\/j.jet.2019.01.006","article-title":"Evolved attitudes to idiosyncratic and aggregate risk in age-structured populations","volume":"181","author":"Robson","year":"2019","journal-title":"J. Econ. Theory"},{"year":"1997","series-title":"Evolutionary Game Theory","author":"Weibull","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617_br0290"}],"container-title":["Journal of Economic Theory"],"original-title":[],"language":"en","link":[{"URL":"https:\/\/api.elsevier.com\/content\/article\/PII:S0022053123000133?httpAccept=text\/xml","content-type":"text\/xml","content-version":"vor","intended-application":"text-mining"},{"URL":"https:\/\/api.elsevier.com\/content\/article\/PII:S0022053123000133?httpAccept=text\/plain","content-type":"text\/plain","content-version":"vor","intended-application":"text-mining"}],"deposited":{"date-parts":[[2024,3,11]],"date-time":"2024-03-11T17:06:58Z","timestamp":1710176818000},"score":1,"resource":{"primary":{"URL":"https:\/\/linkinghub.elsevier.com\/retrieve\/pii\/S0022053123000133"}},"subtitle":[],"short-title":[],"issued":{"date-parts":[[2023,3]]},"references-count":29,"alternative-id":["S0022053123000133"],"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617","relation":{},"ISSN":["0022-0531"],"issn-type":[{"type":"print","value":"0022-0531"}],"subject":[],"published":{"date-parts":[[2023,3]]},"assertion":[{"value":"Elsevier","name":"publisher","label":"This article is maintained by"},{"value":"Evolutionary foundation for heterogeneity in risk aversion","name":"articletitle","label":"Article Title"},{"value":"Journal of Economic Theory","name":"journaltitle","label":"Journal Title"},{"value":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.1016\/j.jet.2023.105617","name":"articlelink","label":"CrossRef DOI link to publisher maintained version"},{"value":"article","name":"content_type","label":"Content Type"},{"value":"\u00a9 2023 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.","name":"copyright","label":"Copyright"}],"article-number":"105617"}}