{"status":"ok","message-type":"work","message-version":"1.0.0","message":{"indexed":{"date-parts":[[2024,8,13]],"date-time":"2024-08-13T13:52:54Z","timestamp":1723557174697},"reference-count":17,"publisher":"Elsevier BV","license":[{"start":{"date-parts":[[2016,5,1]],"date-time":"2016-05-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1462060800000},"content-version":"tdm","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/www.elsevier.com\/tdm\/userlicense\/1.0\/"}],"content-domain":{"domain":["elsevier.com","sciencedirect.com"],"crossmark-restriction":true},"short-container-title":["Journal of Economic Theory"],"published-print":{"date-parts":[[2016,5]]},"DOI":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007","type":"journal-article","created":{"date-parts":[[2016,1,26]],"date-time":"2016-01-26T10:46:10Z","timestamp":1453805170000},"page":"141-166","update-policy":"http:\/\/dx.doi.org\/10.1016\/elsevier_cm_policy","source":"Crossref","is-referenced-by-count":34,"special_numbering":"C","title":["Welfare effects of taxation in oligopolistic markets"],"prefix":"10.1016","volume":"163","author":[{"given":"Jonas","family":"H\u00e4ckner","sequence":"first","affiliation":[]},{"given":"Mathias","family":"Herzing","sequence":"additional","affiliation":[]}],"member":"78","reference":[{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0010","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"451","DOI":"10.1146\/annurev.economics.050708.142910","article-title":"Sufficient statistics for welfare analysis: a bridge between structural and reduced-form methods","volume":"1","author":"Chetty","year":"2009","journal-title":"Annu. Rev. Econ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0020","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"351","DOI":"10.1016\/0047-2727(92)90073-O","article-title":"The comparison between ad valorem and specific taxation under imperfect competition","volume":"49","author":"Delipalla","year":"1992","journal-title":"J. Public Econ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0030","first-page":"297","article-title":"Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity","volume":"67","author":"Dixit","year":"1977","journal-title":"Am. Econ. Rev."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0040","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"20","DOI":"10.2307\/3003317","article-title":"A model of duopoly suggesting a theory of entry barriers","volume":"10","author":"Dixit","year":"1979","journal-title":"Bell J. Econ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0050","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"835","DOI":"10.1016\/j.ijindorg.2004.04.002","article-title":"Idiosyncratic shocks in an asymmetric Cournot oligopoly","volume":"22","author":"F\u00e9vrier","year":"2004","journal-title":"Int. J. Ind. Organ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0060","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"355","DOI":"10.2307\/2555893","article-title":"Testing static oligopoly models: conduct and cost in the sugar industry, 1890\u20131914","volume":"29","author":"Genesove","year":"1998","journal-title":"Rand J. Econ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0070","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"233","DOI":"10.1006\/jeth.2000.2654","article-title":"A note on price and quantity competition in differentiated oligopolies","volume":"93","author":"H\u00e4ckner","year":"2000","journal-title":"J. Econ. Theory"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0080","first-page":"58","article-title":"The measurement of waste","volume":"54","author":"Harberger","year":"1964","journal-title":"Am. Econ. Rev."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0090","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"546","DOI":"10.2307\/2555525","article-title":"Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly","volume":"15","author":"Singh","year":"1984","journal-title":"Rand J. Econ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0100","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"217","DOI":"10.2307\/2297319","article-title":"Product selection, fixed costs, and monopolistic competition","volume":"43","author":"Spence","year":"1976","journal-title":"Rev. Econ. Stud."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0110","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"323","DOI":"10.1007\/s10657-005-4199-3","article-title":"To what extent are cost savings passed on to consumers? An oligopoly approach","volume":"20","author":"ten Kate","year":"2005","journal-title":"Eur. J. Law Econ."},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0120","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"532","DOI":"10.1177\/1091142113496129","article-title":"Ad valorem versus unit taxes in oligopoly and endogenous market conduct","volume":"42","author":"Vetter","year":"2014","journal-title":"Public Finance Rev."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0130","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"173","DOI":"10.1016\/j.ijindorg.2006.02.003","article-title":"Welfare reductions from small cost reductions in differentiated oligopoly","volume":"25","author":"Wang","year":"2007","journal-title":"Int. J. Ind. Organ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0140","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"245","DOI":"10.5235\/ecj.v1n2.245","article-title":"The effects of merger efficiencies on consumers of differentiated products","volume":"1","author":"Werden","year":"2005","journal-title":"Eur. Compet. J."},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0150","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"528","DOI":"10.1086\/670401","article-title":"Pass-through as an economic tool: principles of incidence under imperfect competition","volume":"121","author":"Weyl","year":"2013","journal-title":"J. Polit. Econ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0160","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"455","DOI":"10.1016\/S0167-7187(99)00050-8","article-title":"A characterization for the negative welfare effects of cost reduction in Cournot oligopoly","volume":"19","author":"Zhao","year":"2001","journal-title":"Int. J. Ind. Organ."},{"key":"10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007_br0170","series-title":"Competition and cost pass-through in differentiated oligopolies","author":"Zimmerman","year":"2010"}],"container-title":["Journal of Economic Theory"],"original-title":[],"language":"en","link":[{"URL":"https:\/\/api.elsevier.com\/content\/article\/PII:S0022053116000089?httpAccept=text\/xml","content-type":"text\/xml","content-version":"vor","intended-application":"text-mining"},{"URL":"https:\/\/api.elsevier.com\/content\/article\/PII:S0022053116000089?httpAccept=text\/plain","content-type":"text\/plain","content-version":"vor","intended-application":"text-mining"}],"deposited":{"date-parts":[[2018,9,15]],"date-time":"2018-09-15T19:55:01Z","timestamp":1537041301000},"score":1,"resource":{"primary":{"URL":"https:\/\/linkinghub.elsevier.com\/retrieve\/pii\/S0022053116000089"}},"subtitle":[],"short-title":[],"issued":{"date-parts":[[2016,5]]},"references-count":17,"alternative-id":["S0022053116000089"],"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007","relation":{},"ISSN":["0022-0531"],"issn-type":[{"value":"0022-0531","type":"print"}],"subject":[],"published":{"date-parts":[[2016,5]]},"assertion":[{"value":"Elsevier","name":"publisher","label":"This article is maintained by"},{"value":"Welfare effects of taxation in oligopolistic markets","name":"articletitle","label":"Article Title"},{"value":"Journal of Economic Theory","name":"journaltitle","label":"Journal Title"},{"value":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.1016\/j.jet.2016.01.007","name":"articlelink","label":"CrossRef DOI link to publisher maintained version"},{"value":"article","name":"content_type","label":"Content Type"},{"value":"\u00a9 2016 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.","name":"copyright","label":"Copyright"}]}}