{"status":"ok","message-type":"work","message-version":"1.0.0","message":{"indexed":{"date-parts":[[2024,9,11]],"date-time":"2024-09-11T03:11:05Z","timestamp":1726024265476},"reference-count":69,"publisher":"Elsevier BV","issue":"3","license":[{"start":{"date-parts":[[2019,8,1]],"date-time":"2019-08-01T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1564617600000},"content-version":"tdm","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"https:\/\/www.elsevier.com\/tdm\/userlicense\/1.0\/"},{"start":{"date-parts":[[2019,7,22]],"date-time":"2019-07-22T00:00:00Z","timestamp":1563753600000},"content-version":"vor","delay-in-days":0,"URL":"http:\/\/creativecommons.org\/licenses\/by\/4.0\/"}],"content-domain":{"domain":["elsevier.com","sciencedirect.com"],"crossmark-restriction":true},"short-container-title":["European Journal of Operational Research"],"published-print":{"date-parts":[[2019,8]]},"DOI":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019","type":"journal-article","created":{"date-parts":[[2019,1,16]],"date-time":"2019-01-16T16:46:27Z","timestamp":1547657187000},"page":"1034-1043","update-policy":"http:\/\/dx.doi.org\/10.1016\/elsevier_cm_policy","source":"Crossref","is-referenced-by-count":21,"title":["Focus theory of choice and its application to resolving the St. Petersburg, Allais, and Ellsberg paradoxes and other anomalies"],"prefix":"10.1016","volume":"276","author":[{"ORCID":"http:\/\/orcid.org\/0000-0001-9841-1673","authenticated-orcid":false,"given":"Peijun","family":"Guo","sequence":"first","affiliation":[]}],"member":"78","reference":[{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0001","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"503","DOI":"10.2307\/1907921","article-title":"Le comportement de l'homme rationnel devant le risque: Critique des postulats et axiomes de l'ecole am\u00e9ricaine","volume":"21","author":"Allais","year":"1953","journal-title":"Econometrica"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0002","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"806","DOI":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2015.09.055","article-title":"An outlook on behavioural OR \u2013 Three tasks, three pitfalls, one definition","volume":"249","author":"Becker","year":"2016","journal-title":"European Journal of Operational Research"},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0003","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"677","DOI":"10.1287\/mnsc.1040.0352","article-title":"Back to the St. Petersburg paradox?","volume":"51","author":"Blavatskyy","year":"2005","journal-title":"Management Science"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0004","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"796","DOI":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2015.09.034","article-title":"The what, the why and the how of behavioural operational research\u2014An invitation to potential sceptics","volume":"249","author":"Brocklesby","year":"2016","journal-title":"European Journal of Operational Research"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0005","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"1243","DOI":"10.1093\/qje\/qjs018","article-title":"Salience theory of choice under risk","volume":"127","author":"Bordalo","year":"2012","journal-title":"The Quarterly Journal of Economics"},{"issue":"October","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0006","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"166","DOI":"10.1016\/j.actpsy.2014.08.008","article-title":"Attention in risky choice","volume":"152","author":"Brandst\u00e4tter","year":"2014","journal-title":"Acta Psychologica"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0007","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"409","DOI":"10.1037\/0033-295X.113.2.409","article-title":"The priority heuristic: Making choices without trade-offs","volume":"113","author":"Brandst\u00e4tter","year":"2006","journal-title":"Psychological Review"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0008","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"575","DOI":"10.1257\/aer.103.3.575","article-title":"Estimating the effect of salience in wholesale and retail car markets","volume":"103","author":"Busse","year":"2013","journal-title":"American Economic Review"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0009","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"693","DOI":"10.3982\/ECTA11733","article-title":"Cautious expected utility and the certainty effect","volume":"83","author":"Cerreia-Vioglio","year":"2015","journal-title":"Econometrica"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0001e","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"36","DOI":"10.1287\/msom.2016.0590","article-title":"Measuring the bullwhip effect: Discrepancy and alignment between information and material flows","volume":"19","author":"Chen","year":"2017","journal-title":"Manufacturing & Service Operations Management"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0001d","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"323","DOI":"10.1287\/mnsc.1050.0436","article-title":"Behavioral causes of the bullwhip effect and the observed value of inventory information","volume":"52","author":"Croson","year":"2006","journal-title":"Management Science"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0010","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"125","DOI":"10.3982\/TE798","article-title":"Reason-based choice: A bargaining rationale for the attraction and compromise effects","volume":"7","author":"de Clippel","year":"2012","journal-title":"Theoretical Economics"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0011","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"459","DOI":"10.1016\/S0377-2217(99)00473-7","article-title":"Decision-theoretic foundations of possibility theory","volume":"128","author":"Dubois","year":"2001","journal-title":"European Journal of Operational Research"},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0012","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"643","DOI":"10.2307\/1884324","article-title":"Risk, ambiguity and Savage axioms","volume":"75","author":"Ellsberg","year":"1961","journal-title":"The Quarterly Journal of Economics"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0013","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"234","DOI":"10.1111\/j.1467-6419.2010.00641.x","article-title":"Decision theory under ambiguity","volume":"26","author":"Etner","year":"2012","journal-title":"Journal of Economic Surveys"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0014","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"791","DOI":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2015.10.034","article-title":"Behavioural operational research: Returning to the roots of the OR profession","volume":"249","author":"Franco","year":"2016","journal-title":"European Journal of Operational Research"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0015","series-title":"Choosing the right pond: Human behavior and the quest for status","author":"Frank","year":"1985"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0016","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"255","DOI":"10.3982\/ECTA9621","article-title":"Subjective expected utility with incomplete preferences","volume":"81","author":"Galaabaatar","year":"2013","journal-title":"Econometrica"},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0001b","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"453","DOI":"10.1111\/j.1937-5956.2009.01110.x","article-title":"Anatomy of a newsvendor decision: Observations from a verbal protocol analysis","volume":"19","author":"Gavirneni","year":"2010","journal-title":"Production and Operations Management"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0017","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"450","DOI":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2003.05.004","article-title":"Two axiomatic approaches to decision making using possibility theory","volume":"162","author":"Giang","year":"2005","journal-title":"European Journal of Operational Research"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0018","series-title":"Subjective probability","first-page":"129","article-title":"Why the distinction between single-event probabilities and frequencies is important for psychology (and Vice-Versa)","author":"Gigerenzer","year":"1994"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0019","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"451","DOI":"10.1146\/annurev-psych-120709-145346","article-title":"Heuristic decision making","volume":"62","author":"Gigerenzer","year":"2011","journal-title":"Annual Review of Psychology"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0020","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"65","DOI":"10.1016\/0304-4068(87)90022-X","article-title":"Expected utility with purely subjective nonadditive probabilities","volume":"16","author":"Gilboa","year":"1987","journal-title":"Journal of Mathematical Economics"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0021","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"71","DOI":"10.1002\/bdm.684","article-title":"An eye-tracking study on information processing in risky decisions: Evidence for compensatory strategies based on automatic processes","volume":"24","author":"Glockner","year":"2011","journal-title":"Journal of Behavioral Decision Making"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0022","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"1","DOI":"10.3982\/ECTA9188","article-title":"Expected uncertain utility theory","volume":"82","author":"Gul","year":"2014","journal-title":"Econometrica"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0023","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"213","DOI":"10.1504\/IJIDS.2010.033449","article-title":"One-shot decision approach and its application to duopoly market","volume":"2","author":"Guo","year":"2010","journal-title":"International Journal of Information and Decision Sciences"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0024","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"238","DOI":"10.53383\/100127","article-title":"Private real estate investment analysis within a one-shot decision framework","volume":"13","author":"Guo","year":"2010","journal-title":"International Real Estate Review"},{"issue":"5","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0025","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"917","DOI":"10.1109\/TSMCA.2010.2093891","article-title":"One-shot decision theory","volume":"41","author":"Guo","year":"2011","journal-title":"IEEE Transactions on Systems Man and Cybernetics \u2013 Part A Systems and Humans"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0026","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"612","DOI":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2013.12.038","article-title":"Approaches to multistage one-shot decision making","volume":"236","author":"Guo","year":"2014","journal-title":"European Journal of Operational Research"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0027","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"523","DOI":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2014.05.028","article-title":"Newsvendor models for innovative products with one-shot decision theory","volume":"239","author":"Guo","year":"2014","journal-title":"European Journal of Operational Research"},{"issue":"6","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0028","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"786","DOI":"10.1080\/18756891.2010.9727741","article-title":"Duopoly market analysis within one-shot decision framework with asymmetric possibilistic information","volume":"3","author":"Guo","year":"2010","journal-title":"International Journal of Computational Intelligence System"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0029","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"594","DOI":"10.2307\/1959090","article-title":"Can the maximin principle serve as a basis for morality? A critique of John Rawls's theory","volume":"69","author":"Harsanyi","year":"1975","journal-title":"American Political Science Review"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0030","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"263","DOI":"10.2307\/1914185","article-title":"Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk","volume":"47","author":"Kahneman","year":"1979","journal-title":"Econometrica"},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0031","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"341","DOI":"10.1037\/0003-066X.39.4.341","article-title":"Choices, values, and frames","volume":"39","author":"Kahneman","year":"1984","journal-title":"American Psychologist"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0032","series-title":"Heuristics and biases: The psychology of intuitive judgment","first-page":"49","article-title":"Representativeness revisited: Attribute substitution in intuitive judgment","author":"Kahneman","year":"2002"},{"issue":"5","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0033","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"2206","DOI":"10.1257\/aer.102.5.2206","article-title":"Heuristic thinking and limited attention in the car market","volume":"102","author":"Lacetera","year":"2012","journal-title":"American Economic Review"},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0001c","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"546","DOI":"10.1287\/mnsc.43.4.546","article-title":"Information distortion in a supply chain: The bullwhip effect","volume":"43","author":"Lee","year":"1997","journal-title":"Management Science"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0034","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"47","DOI":"10.1016\/j.fss.2015.01.005","article-title":"Possibilistic individual multi-period consumption\u2013investment models","volume":"274","author":"Li","year":"2015","journal-title":"Fuzzy Sets and Systems"},{"issue":"5","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0035","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"1824","DOI":"10.1257\/aer.97.5.1824","article-title":"Sequentially rationalizable choice","volume":"97","author":"Manzini","year":"2007","journal-title":"American Economic Review"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0036","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"343","DOI":"10.1016\/S0166-4115(08)62243-8","article-title":"Decision rules and the search for a dominance structure: Towards a process model of decision making","volume":"14","author":"Montgomery","year":"1983","journal-title":"Advances in Psychology"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0037","series-title":"Theory of games and economic behavior","author":"von Neumann","year":"1944"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0038","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"231","DOI":"10.1037\/0033-295X.84.3.231","article-title":"Telling more than we can know: Verbal reports on mental processes","volume":"84","author":"Nisbett","year":"1977","journal-title":"Psychological Review"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0039","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"87","DOI":"10.1146\/annurev.ps.43.020192.000511","article-title":"Behavioral decision research: A constructive processing perspective","volume":"43","author":"Payne","year":"1992","journal-title":"Annual Review of Psychology"},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0040","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"323","DOI":"10.1016\/0167-2681(82)90008-7","article-title":"A theory of anticipated utility","volume":"3","author":"Quiggin","year":"1982","journal-title":"Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0041","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"665","DOI":"10.1007\/s00199-005-0641-6","article-title":"Cumulative prospect theory and the St. Petersburg paradox","volume":"28","author":"Rieger","year":"2006","journal-title":"Economic Theory"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0042","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"145","DOI":"10.1016\/0022-0531(88)90154-8","article-title":"Similarity and decision-making under risk (Is there a utility theory resolution to the Allais paradox?)","volume":"46","author":"Rubinstein","year":"1988","journal-title":"Journal of Economic Theory"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0043","series-title":"Modeling bounded rationality","author":"Rubinstein","year":"1998"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0044","series-title":"The foundations of statistics","author":"Savage","year":"1954"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0045","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"571","DOI":"10.2307\/1911053","article-title":"Subjective probability and expected utility without additivity","volume":"57","author":"Schmeidler","year":"1989","journal-title":"Econometrica"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0001a","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"404","DOI":"10.1287\/mnsc.46.3.404.12070","article-title":"Decision bias in the newsvendor problem with a known demand distribution: Experimental evidence","volume":"46","author":"Schweitzer","year":"2000","journal-title":"Management Science"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0046","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"175","DOI":"10.2307\/2526866","article-title":"The Ellsberg paradox and risk aversion: An anticipated utility approach","volume":"28","author":"Segal","year":"1987","journal-title":"International Economic Review"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0047","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"349","DOI":"10.2307\/2938207","article-title":"Two-stage lotteries without the reduction axiom","volume":"58","author":"Segal","year":"1990","journal-title":"Econometrica"},{"issue":"1-2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0048","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"11","DOI":"10.1016\/0010-0277(93)90034-S","article-title":"Reason-based choice","volume":"49","author":"Shafir","year":"1993","journal-title":"Cognition"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0049","series-title":"Method and appraisal in economics","first-page":"129","article-title":"From substantive to procedural rationality","author":"Simon","year":"1976"},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0050","first-page":"493","article-title":"Rational decision making in business organizations","volume":"69","author":"Simon","year":"1979","journal-title":"American Economic Review"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0051","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"373","DOI":"10.1016\/S0167-2681(98)00089-4","article-title":"Is more always better? A survey on positional concerns","volume":"37","author":"Solnick","year":"1998","journal-title":"Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0052","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"332","DOI":"10.1257\/jel.38.2.332","article-title":"Developments in non-expected utility theory: The hunt for a descriptive theory of choice under risk","volume":"38","author":"Starmer","year":"2000","journal-title":"Journal of Economic Literature"},{"issue":"1","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0053","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"47","DOI":"10.3982\/ECTA8155","article-title":"Axiomatic foundations of multiplier preferences","volume":"79","author":"Strzalecki","year":"2011","journal-title":"Econometrica"},{"issue":"2\u20133","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0054","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"116","DOI":"10.1002\/bdm.1854","article-title":"Eye movements in risky choice","volume":"29","author":"Stewart","year":"2016","journal-title":"Journal of Behavioral Decision Making"},{"issue":"4481","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0055","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"453","DOI":"10.1126\/science.7455683","article-title":"The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice","volume":"211","author":"Tversky","year":"1981","journal-title":"Science"},{"issue":"4, Part 2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0056","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"S251","DOI":"10.1086\/296365","article-title":"Rational choice and the framing of decisions","volume":"59","author":"Tversky","year":"1986","journal-title":"Journal of Business"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0057","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"715","DOI":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2018.02.025","article-title":"Transshipments in supply chains: A behavioral investigation","volume":"269","author":"Villa","year":"2018","journal-title":"European Journal of Operational Research"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0058","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"994","DOI":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2017.03.024","article-title":"Behavioral models for first-price sealed-bid auctions with the one-shot decision theory","volume":"261","author":"Wang","year":"2017","journal-title":"European Journal of Operational Research"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0059","first-page":"429","article-title":"Moderation of preference reversals in the long run","volume":"16","author":"Wedell","year":"1990","journal-title":"Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance"},{"issue":"4","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0060","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"499","DOI":"10.2307\/1422997","article-title":"Contemplating single versus multiple encounters of a risky prospect","volume":"107","author":"Wedell","year":"1994","journal-title":"American Journal of Psychology"},{"issue":"3","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0061","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"827","DOI":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2015.07.032","article-title":"Behavioural operational research: Towards a framework for understanding behaviour in OR interventions","volume":"249","author":"White","year":"2016","journal-title":"European Journal of Operational Research"},{"issue":"2\u20133","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0062","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"169","DOI":"10.1002\/bdm.1943","article-title":"A scanpath analysis of the risky decision-making process","volume":"29","author":"Zhou","year":"2016","journal-title":"Journal of Behavioral Decision Making"},{"key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0063","series-title":"Proceedings of IEEE international conference on industrial engineering and engineering management","article-title":"The one-shot decision theory based production planning models","author":"Zhu","year":"2016"},{"issue":"2","key":"10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019_bib0064","doi-asserted-by":"crossref","first-page":"255","DOI":"10.1007\/s00186-017-0592-2","article-title":"Approaches to four types of bilevel programming problems with nonconvex nonsmooth lower level programs and their applications to newsvendor problems","volume":"86","author":"Zhu","year":"2017","journal-title":"Mathematical Methods of Operations Research"}],"container-title":["European Journal of Operational Research"],"original-title":[],"language":"en","link":[{"URL":"https:\/\/api.elsevier.com\/content\/article\/PII:S0377221719300219?httpAccept=text\/xml","content-type":"text\/xml","content-version":"vor","intended-application":"text-mining"},{"URL":"https:\/\/api.elsevier.com\/content\/article\/PII:S0377221719300219?httpAccept=text\/plain","content-type":"text\/plain","content-version":"vor","intended-application":"text-mining"}],"deposited":{"date-parts":[[2022,9,10]],"date-time":"2022-09-10T11:30:16Z","timestamp":1662809416000},"score":1,"resource":{"primary":{"URL":"https:\/\/linkinghub.elsevier.com\/retrieve\/pii\/S0377221719300219"}},"subtitle":[],"short-title":[],"issued":{"date-parts":[[2019,8]]},"references-count":69,"journal-issue":{"issue":"3","published-print":{"date-parts":[[2019,8]]}},"alternative-id":["S0377221719300219"],"URL":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019","relation":{},"ISSN":["0377-2217"],"issn-type":[{"value":"0377-2217","type":"print"}],"subject":[],"published":{"date-parts":[[2019,8]]},"assertion":[{"value":"Elsevier","name":"publisher","label":"This article is maintained by"},{"value":"Focus theory of choice and its application to resolving the St. Petersburg, Allais, and Ellsberg paradoxes and other anomalies","name":"articletitle","label":"Article Title"},{"value":"European Journal of Operational Research","name":"journaltitle","label":"Journal Title"},{"value":"https:\/\/doi.org\/10.1016\/j.ejor.2019.01.019","name":"articlelink","label":"CrossRef DOI link to publisher maintained version"},{"value":"article","name":"content_type","label":"Content Type"},{"value":"\u00a9 2019 The Author. Published by Elsevier B.V.","name":"copyright","label":"Copyright"}]}}